Cataloging-in-Publication data provided by the Inter-American Development Bank

Cataloging-in-Publication data provided by the Inter-American Development Bank
Cataloging-in-Publication data provided by the Inter-American Development Bank

Inter-American Development Bank Banco Interamericano de Desarrollo Latin American Research Network Red de Centros de Investigación Research Network Working Paper #R-510

Political Institutions, Policymaking Processes, and Policy Outcomes: The Case of Uruguay

by

Mario Bergara (coordinator)*

Andrés Pereyra*

Ruben Tansini* Adolfo Garcé**

Daniel Chasquetti**

Daniel Buquet**

Juan Andrés Moraes**

*Departamento de Economía, Universidad de la República Oriental

del Uruguay

**Instituto de Ciencia Política, Universidad de la República Oriental del

Uruguay

March 2006

Cataloging-in-Publication data provided by the

Inter-American Development Bank

Felipe Herrera Library

Political institutions, policymaking processes, and policy outcomes : the case of Uruguay / by Mario Bergara (coordinator) … [et al.].

p. cm.

(Research Network Working papers ; R-510)

Includes bibliographical references.

1. State, The.

2. Uruguay—Social policy.

3. Uruguay—Economic policy. I. Bergara, Mario. II. Inter-American Development Bank. Research Dept. III. Latin American Research Network. IV. Series.

320.1 P445--------dc22

?2006

Inter-American Development Bank

1300 New York Avenue, N.W.

Washington, DC 20577

The views and interpretations in this document are those of the authors and should not be attributed to the Inter-American Development Bank, or to any individual acting on its behalf.

This paper may be freely reproduced provided credit is given to the Research Department, Inter-American Development Bank.

The Research Department (RES) produces a quarterly newsletter, IDEA (Ideas for Development in the Americas), as well as working papers and books on diverse economic issues. To obtain a complete list of RES publications, and read or download them please visit our web site at: https://www.360docs.net/doc/2018775306.html,/res.

Abstract

Uruguay generates a variety of policy outcomes. First, there are relatively stable policies, such as those allowing for the commercial and financial openness of the country. Then there are inflexible and low-quality policies, such as those related to social policies, some areas of state reform (civil servants’ wages and hiring mechanisms), the bankruptcy regime, etc. Finally, there are volatile outcomes resulting from economic shocks, such as those related to discretionary public spending. In the cases in which historical precedence or the availability of external enforcement devices do not lead to relatively stable policies, the main outer feature of Uruguayan policies is rigidity. The source of rigidity appears to be a mixture of institutional factors (multiple veto points, factionalized parties and direct democracy mechanisms) and political conflict (divergent policy preferences), in which it is very costly to move from the status quo due to the credible threat of policy reversal. Political institutions in Uruguay are conducive to achieving political compromise in the short run, but cannot effectively cooperate in establishing stable and flexible policies in the long run. The difficulty in achieving intertemporal political exchanges is consistent with the main characteristics of the political environment: a large number of key political actors and veto points, a relevant amount of unobservable political maneuvering, poor enforcement technologies in the economic arena, a politically influenced bureaucracy, political exchanges occurring outside the legislative arena, a particular constellation of parties and preferences and costly policymaking and institutional changes.

1. Introduction

Uruguay is the most enduring democracy in Latin America. To a large extent, its long-lasting democratic process has been sustained by an institutionalized party system, in which only two parties (Partido Colorado and Partido Nacional) have dominated the political scene since the country was established. In the long run, therefore, the Uruguayan political system reflects an important level of stability and continuity that makes it almost an exception in the regional context. Since the return to democracy in 1985, Uruguay has experienced a high degree of political inclusion and political and social participation. Intensive negotiations took place between political parties and social organizations, each holding a significant degree of power. Nevertheless, it has not been easy to reach agreement in a number of important policy areas.

Uruguay is a pluralistic system with strong parties and is a highly participative democracy. Indeed, the pluralism in the political institutions and party system is nourished by the participation of citizens and social groups, especially through certain procedures of “direct” democracy (plebiscites, referendums) on constitutional matters, human rights issues and privatizations. The key role played by the state stems from a long historical process of political leadership and party performance, which has had long-lasting effects on citizenship and civic culture.

Uruguayan public opinion profiles (Latinobarómetro poll series 1995-2002) show the citizen/voters’ attachment to democratic culture and the state: (i) Uruguay and Costa Rica have the greatest support for democracy and the lowest tolerance of non-democratic regimes. (ii) Uruguay has the highest level of interpersonal trust and Uruguayans have the most confidence in their political parties. Trust in government is above average, but is a long way from the top. (iii) Uruguay’s endorsement of the free-market economy is by far the lowest in Latin America. (iv) Only Argentina has a more negative view of privatization than Uruguay.

Uruguayan public opinion exhibits high levels of statism. Uruguayans’ preference for state over market was explicitly demonstrated in referenda: one opposing the privatization of the state-owned telephone company in 1992 and one opposing a law which would have allowed the state-owned oil company to associate with a private partner in 2003. In the first instance, 72 percent of the electorate voted against the law, and in the latter 62 percent did so. There also were other situations when the mere threat of a referendum blocked market-oriented reforms, such as when Congress revoked articles that would have allowed for the partial privatization of

the state-owned cell phone company in 2002 immediately after the signatures calling for referendum against them were collected.

But this Uruguayan preference for the state not only implies that resources must be concentrated in the state apparatus, but also that the state should have the ability to satisfy every kind of “social” demand. In the same way that market-oriented reformers think that privatization serves to tie their hands in terms of resource allocation, state-oriented supporters believe state-controlled, discretionary resource allocation is the only way to meet the needs of different “weak” interest groups (pensioners, unions, debtors, etc.). Therefore, people tend to oppose not only market-oriented reforms, but also any kind of reforms that pretend to define rules precisely and provide rationality to public administration. This last feature of the Uruguayan political landscape sits well with constituency-oriented politicians, who prefer to manage resources in a discretionary way rather than in a more institutionalized manner.

In 2000, around 80 percent of Uruguayans thought that the state should control most public companies. This opinion was shared by 90 percent of those who consider themselves to be left wing, 82 percent of centrists, and 71 percent of those who consider themselves to be located on the right side of the ideological spectrum. More recently, the public has favored “de-monopolization;” 50 percent of those surveyed see it as a positive option, including 44 percent of those who think of themselves as being on the left. Moreover, 48 percent of the people surveyed believe that it is a good thing for private capital to be involved in the development of public companies, while 35 percent think that de-monopolization is inconvenient (Cifra Survey, 2000).

The democratic values of the Uruguayan people are associated with the centrality of politics in daily life. However, a declining interest in politics has been observed in recent years, although it tends to increase during elections. This process is the result of a long period of public discontentment that can be traced back to the mid-1950s, when the import-substitution model of development suffered a crisis. From that moment on, the idea that the country is in crisis and in a constant state of deterioration has become an idiosyncratic feature of Uruguayan culture. It can be argued that the recent electoral growth of the left has been fed by Uruguayan voters’ political disenchantment, which began long before the left’s success in the electoral arena. The impact of this disenchantment does not consist exclusively of widening the left’s electoral base but is also reflected in an electoral circulation between and within the traditional parties.

Some of the distinctive features of Uruguayan democracy, reflected in its institutions (parties and party system) and in the preferences of public opinion, make it almost an exception in the Latin American context. In those contexts where the party system is highly institutionalized, parties and their leaders help shape the preferences of voters, but they also follow public opinion.1 Because of this, the preferences of the public are, as such, indiscernible from the policy preferences of the leadership and of the Uruguayan parties in general. In other words, Uruguayan parties strongly support the democratic process and its institutions, and the party system reveals a certain level of polarization regarding some policy issues such as state participation in the economy.

Uruguay has a pattern of implementing policies and reforms that permits progress in an incremental fashion. This incremental feature of the Uruguayan PMP is the result of the prevailing institutional engineering (electoral and regime rules) and the transformation of the party system in recent years (electoral realignment and substantive changes in party functions and strategies).

Uruguayan political parties are the main actors both in the government and in the opposition, shaping the processes and contents of major public policies. Particular attention shall be paid to the shift from “triangle” politics to bloc politics. To the extent that the leftist front (the FA) grows, the Blancos and the Colorados—who have been rivals throughout Uruguayan history and have been competing against each other in the new democratic period—are nevertheless going through a process of “convergence.” Even when they are still competing, they reach compromises and form coalitions, thus creating a political pole and an ideological family. On the other side, the leftist FA is developing as the dominant opposition force, putting forward its positions against liberal initiatives and privatization. These patterns of competition and cooperation are central to explaining the different chapters of the politics of reform and their outcomes.

Uruguay is able to generate different kinds of policy results. First, there are relatively stable policies, such as those allowing for the commercial and financial openness of the country. Second are policies characterized by a low volatility, but which are inflexible and of low quality,

1 Even though this seems as if politicians follow public opinion preferences, during direct democracy events like plebiscites and referenda, party guidelines have proven to be the decisive factor over the outcome. As suggested by Altman (2002): “When Uruguayans go to the polls to decide a popular initiative, they mainly take into considertion their political faction’s suggestion.”

such as those related to social policies, some areas of state reform (civil servants’ wages and hiring mechanisms), the bankruptcy regime, etc. Finally there are volatile outcomes resulting from economic shocks, such as those related to discretionary public spending.

Consistent with the analytic framework, the resulting political decisions do not depend solely on the political institutions but also on the transaction-cost characteristics of the different arenas, such as political and social preferences, the demands of intertemporal exchanges, different sets of political and social actors and the availability of enforcement mechanisms. This constellation of policies can emerge from an institutional environment that does not facilitate intertemporal exchanges and cooperation, due to the relevant ingredients contained in the description of political institutions.

In the cases in which policies are relatively stable, political preferences tend to be convergent and the expected gains from political conflict are not significant. Additionally, external enforcement mechanisms could be available through strategies such as “tying one’s hands.” The commitment technology was not provided by the working of the political system itself, but via external “enforcers.” Here historical precedence could also play a key role, making it very costly to reverse policies in several areas. In the cases in which policies are rigid and low-quality, political preferences tend to diverge but the cost of implementing safeguards is relatively low. The rigidity emerges from the need for political safeguards, and the low volatility is consistent with the fact that institutional change is very costly in Uruguay. This can be characterized by the presence of political threats and the perception of politicians that the probability and costs of having their policies reversed are high. In the cases of volatile outcomes, this result is determined by the absence of stable and adaptable policies across economic shocks. Decisions here are delegated by the Executive, particularly in the implementation stage. This is not the result of political conflict, but of an inability to set rules with a long-term perspective.

Political institutions in Uruguay are conducive to political compromise in the short run, but not to effective cooperation regarding stable and flexible policies in the long run. With the new constellation of parties and political preferences, there is a greater uncertainty about the ability to cooperate in the future.

The difficulty in achieving intertemporal political exchanges is consistent with some characteristics of the political environment. The number of key political actors and veto points in several areas is relatively large and does not facilitate cooperation, even if political leaders have

some intertemporal linkages. A relevant amount of political maneuvering is not openly observable, although some transparency emerged in recent administrations. Despite the tradition of a relatively independent judiciary, enforcement technologies are poor in the economic arena; the bureaucracy is crucially influenced by political considerations, relevant and actual delegation has not taken place and the courts are not adequately prepared to handle complex economic issues. Key political exchanges take place outside the legislature and their certainty, observability and enforcement are less obvious in a framework of political fragmentation, a particular constellation of parties and preferences and costly policymaking and institutional change. Additionally, the workings of the policymaking process suggest that intra-period payoffs from non-cooperation are high.

Those areas in which the Executive has broader discretion—and therefore requires less bargaining and cooperation—tend to exhibit more volatile outcomes, since the Executive has some freedom to accommodate them to economic shocks. Again, this is not the result of political conflict but of an inability to set long-term rules in an environment characterized by mostly rigid policies. An example of this is discretionary public spending. In those areas in which a greater participation of the legislature is required and in which the interaction between the Executive and the legislature is more intense, policies tend to be rigid. Social policies are typical examples of this case.

In sum, in the cases in which historical precedence or the availability of external enforcement devices do not lead to relatively stable policies, the main outer feature of Uruguayan policies is rigidity. The source of rigidity appears to be a mixture of institutional factors (multiple veto points, factionalized parties and direct democracy mechanisms) and political conflict (divergent policy preferences), in which it is very costly to move from the status quo because of the credible threat of policy reversal.

2. Characterization of Public Policies in Uruguay

In order to develop a tentative characterization of policies in Uruguay along the dimensions suggested in Spiller, Stein and Tommasi (2003) and Scartascini and Olivera (2003), this section is divided into two parts. The first part provides different accounts of specific policy areas and specific policy cases, offering valuable information regarding trends and specific features of Uruguayan public policies. The second part summarizes the tentative description of the country’s

policies in terms of their stability, their flexibility to adapt to changing socioeconomic conditions, their rigidity, etc.

2.1 Description of Some Specific Policies

This section summarizes a wide range of public policies, including some main economic issues and measures embedded in the state reform program.

Trade policies: The policy of trade opening, understood as the process of systematically lowering tariffs, was first implemented in 1974, and it brought to an end several decades of the import-substitution model of trade policy. This change was a consequence of the fact that the deficit in the balance of trade, which came about following the first oil crisis in 1974, could not be sustained (see Vaillant, 2003). The process of market opening continued throughout the period of the dictatorship, and was not to any great extent reversed when the country returned to democracy in 1985. Uruguay joined MERCOSUR and the tariff structure of the bloc was adopted in 1995, consistent with the process of a general reduction in tariffs. In the early phase of trade liberalization lasting until the early 1990s, a relatively stable group of industries was isolated from foreign competition. The existence of an exceptions list improved the chances of trade reform because it made the reform more palatable in political terms. In the second half of the 1990s, reciprocal trade agreements (preferential or multilateral non-discriminatory) changed the political equilibrium of the previous unilateral trade policy. The number of Uruguayan industries isolated from the liberalization process was drastically reduced. Indeed, geographical reasons largely dictated Uruguay’s decision to join MERCOSUR, although policymakers around the region acknowledge the value of the agreement as a “commitment technology” that increased their autonomy vis à vis domestic interest groups (see Vaillant, 2003). This process of tariff reduction and trade opening can be characterized as a steady movement without reversal, which can be considered as an outer feature of this policy.

It must be stressed that when Uruguay returned to democracy there was no reversal of the policy of openness, although there was pressure for a move in that direction. This pressure was handled using non-tariff instruments, which provided the desired levels of effective protection. In some cases this policy of “contingent protection” was applied to specific sectors (e.g., the automotive and sugar industries), and in other cases to sub-sectors or even to particular firms. This operated as an escape valve, and it meant that the general policy of reducing tariffs was not reversed. Additionally, in 1995, the country adopted the tariff structure agreed to in

MERCOSUR. From then on, discretionary activity in trade policy lessened, and was expressed through managing the so-called lists of exceptions to the common regime of the common external tariff, and exceptions to the free movement of merchandise within the bloc. This was called the adjustment regime. In this sense, policies in the trade area became more public- regarding. Thus the MERCOSUR agreement operated as a mechanism of external enforcement of the policy of openness, limiting the possibility for particular sectors to lobby. It was relatively obvious for all relevant actors that a small country like Uruguay has to be open to the world in terms of trade. What was not so obvious was the fact that opening to imports is the price a country has to pay in order to get into international markets. The Asuncion Treaty represented Uruguay’s fundamental acceptance of the need to effectively open the economy, and served to tie the government hand in terms of granting sectoral privileges, making the policy less private-regarding.

Financial openness: Uruguay started the process of opening the capital account of the balance of payments during the 1970s. The motivation behind this policy was the same as that behind trade opening, namely the 1974 oil crisis and the need to finance the large trade balance deficit that followed. The financial reform aimed to deregulate internal capital markets and liberalize financial operations between the country and the rest of the world. The most important liberalization measures in the financial sector (i) authorized residents to maintain domestic bank accounts in dollars without having to account for the source of those funds, (ii) allowed them to maintain any kind of assets abroad, (iii) authorized the profits and capital of foreign agents to leave the country freely, (iv) allowed non-financial enterprises unrestricted access to foreign credit, (v) authorized commercial banks to accede to foreign credit, and (vi) removed controls on the interest rates in a gradual process that lasted until the late 1970s. As in the trade case, this policy was managed by the Executive, through the Ministry of Finance. Congress did not intervene except to pass certain laws giving powers to the Executive. However, as long as the policy consisted of almost total freedom for capital movements, there was little room for discretion in its implementation.

Since the initiation of the reform, which led to financial opening, there has not been any attempt to hinder the movement of capital between Uruguay and the rest of the world. The economic and financial openness was the result of systematic negotiations with multilateral organizations in the early 1980s. During the 1990s, an important wave of capital inflow

occurred, which in addition to representing visible technological progress in the financial sector, was an endorsement of the global policy. Even during the recent financial crisis in 2002, there were no calls to control capital movements, showing a high level of consensus on preferences related to this issue and stressing the stability of this policy.

Pension system policy: In the early 1990s, Uruguay had a social security system with a single, pay-as-you-go pillar. It was not in imminent danger of collapse, but it did have serious problems connected to (i) a population structure in which pensioners accounted for a very high percentage compared to the economically active population,2 and (ii) the fact that for decades, the social security system had been used as an instrument for political favors. In 1989, as the result of a plebiscite initiated by various pensioners’ and workers’ organizations, rules for the adjustment of pensions were incorporated into the Constitution. The introduction of these rules was probably a reaction to the government’s tendency to use pension adjustments in opportunistic ways, leading to rigidity and reducing its ability to adapt to macroeconomic conditions. This made the economic problems of the social security system worse, and played a part in the political system’s decision to take measures to counteract its slide towards insolvency. In 1995, Congress passed the Social Security Reform Law, which set up a mixed system. It combined an individual capitalization pillar with a pay-as-you-go pillar. The reform was moderate insofar as it is estimated that when the system matures, 75 percent of the contributions will still be made in the public pay-as-you-go pillar. This pillar is administered by the Banco de Previsión Social (BPS), while the individual savings pillar is administered by organizations that were created through the reform—the Pension Fund Administrators (AFAPs). The reform reduced politicians’ ability to manipulate the sector, using pensions as a typical clientelistic resource. In particular, the implementation of work history as part of the reform reduced the ability of politicians to grant benefits on a discretionary basis. As in the case of trade issues, policies here also seem to be getting less private-regarding. The new stakeholders created by law—the administrators of the pension funds—can contribute to the formalization of the pension system (see Forteza, 2003).

2 An illustrative indicator is the Potential Dependency Rate (PDR), which is the ratio between the number of peoples who could potentially be dependent (those younger than 1

3 years old + retired and potential retired people) and the number of people who could potentially enter the labor force (persons between 13 and the retiring age). The PDR was approximately 75 percent at the time of the reform implementation and is estimated to be 65 percent during the next 20 years. In comparison, the PDR in Chile was 55 percent in 2000.

The social security reform temporarily raises the deficit of the system because of the implicit debt of the downsized pay-as-you-go pillar. One of the consequences of this process has to do with the fact that the government induces or even forces the administrators of the pension funds to invest a sizeable part of the fund in public bonds. In essence, the reform was characterized by intense negotiations, involving parties, factions and a large number of interest groups and associations, both in the executive and legislative arenas. The result is a rigid scheme that tries to avoid opportunistic behavior on the part of politicians by making it more costly to grant pensions on a clientelistic basis. The crisis of 2002 cast doubt on the state’s ability to meet government bond payments. An eventual failure to meet these obligations would have meant expropriations from the individual savings system, since this is a big holder of Uruguayan bonds.

Utility markets: Utility services have traditionally been provided by public enterprises enjoying monopolies in their respective spheres of activity. In the 1990s, moderate market-oriented reforms were promoted mainly in the electrical energy, communications and fuel sectors. These reforms aimed to increase competition in the markets for public services and partially privatize the public enterprises. The reforms were carried out through laws that modified the definition of the monopolies of the public enterprises and raised the possibility of bringing private capital into them. In general, they have been challenged through referendums: (i) The 1992 Public Enterprises Law, which partially privatized the state-owned telecommunications enterprise ANTEL, was overturned in 1993 in a referendum initiated by ANTEL’s employee union.(ii) A 1997 law concerning a new regulatory framework for electrical energy was challenged by UTE’s employee union, but this attempt failed. (iii) Legislation that dealt with changes in ANTEL’s charter and the opening of international telephony was challenged, and the government brought about its abolition in 2002 when a referendum on that appeared imminent. (iv) The law for opening the market for refined petroleum products, which eliminated ANCAP′s monopoly over the refining and distributing of these products, and which made it possible for private capital to enter into the public enterprise, was recently overturned by a referendum initiated by ANCAP’s employees. This process is indicative of a lack of basic agreement among the main political groups involved. What is more consensual is the use of these monopolies as strong contributors of resources to the Treasury. This promoted some efficiency improvements in state-owned companies but represents an obstacle in the process of liberalizing utility markets.

In cases where the reforms went through (electricity, and partially in communications), the pace of the implementation has depended on the role the reform policy played at the time, i.e., whether there were (i) objectives related to sectoral reforms, (ii) fiscal objectives, which are much more important during a crisis, or (iii) external constraints, which have speeded the process of electrical interconnection with Argentina or the MERCOSUR bloc. The reform of the electricity sector seems to be a paradigmatic case here, since it is a reform achieved by a law that was not overturned, though seven years later it still has not been implemented.

Interest groups also play a relevant role in resisting some reforms. While unions do so by promoting referenda, other groups defend their interests in a more subtle way in the policy-implementation stage through interactions with the Executive and the political parties.

Broad policies in utility markets tend to be relatively rigid when they are the result of interaction between the legislature and the Executive: (i) the very existence of the state-owned companies is established in the Constitution, (ii) the mechanisms for appointing and firing the board members of these companies are also noted in the Constitution, and (iii) several laws are very specific in terms of operational procedures, eliminating some discretion in terms of business strategies, association with private firms, etc.

Fiscal policies: Since 1990, the tax burden has increased considerably, growing from 25 percent to more than 30 percent of GDP in a decade (the highest possible in the region). The structure of this income remained basically unchanged: the taxes on consumption, the IVA (value added tax) and IMESI (sales tax), accounted for 65 percent of income at the start of the period and stood at the same level at the end. Total income increased because of rises in the rates charged and a widening of the base where the tax was levied.

The tax administration system presents serious drawbacks, showing relatively high levels of evasion. Although there were a number of projects to reform this system, they were not passed approved by Congress. During the period, there was a continual process of creating, abolishing and modifying taxes, and this allowed for a discretional management of fiscal income policy. In particular, tax exemptions were used to give attention to private interests. However, this feature involved a relatively small group of taxes, and the taxation structure that accounted for the greater part of fiscal income remained unchanged.

Expenditure also increased over the decade, but by a smaller proportion than the increase in income. In 1989 a plebiscite that index-linked pensions to the past rate of inflation generated

significant fiscal problems on the spending side. In the five years immediately following the plebiscite, the deficit in the social security administration (the Banco de Previsión Social) jumped from 2.5 percent to 6.3 percent of GDP. The plebiscite had the effect of making social security expenditure non-discretional. In response to this problem, Congress passed a reform of the social security system in 1995. This reform did not change the fact that expenditure on social security remained outside of government control, but it did establish actuarial bases for the system that would be sustainable in the middle and long term.

The amount of salaries paid by the public sector also remained constant (in terms of GDP) throughout the period. The outstanding policy move in this area began in 1996 with the rendering of accounts by a single article3 to avoid having to submit the revised annual budget to Congress (maintaining the five-year budget without any modifications). This had the effect of avoiding discussion and negotiations with the public employee unions, and thus removed the possibility of increasing expenditure in this area. The price the government paid for this strategy was that it made the budget process very inflexible.

Public-sector investment remained stable over the period until 2002, when there was an abrupt fall due to the generalized economic crisis. Fluctuations in the management of public-sector investment have a negative effect and generate harmful cycles, as has been well documented in the case of road infrastructure. Investment in public enterprises also fell as a response to fiscal requirements; investment decisions in state-owned enterprises are now negotiated with the Planning and Budget Office and the Ministry of Finance during bargaining over the transfer of profits.

Almost all of the items on the spending side are essentially rigid and non-discretionary. Broadly speaking, half of public expenditures go to social security and one fourth goes to wages. Interests and debt repayment are also outside government control. Therefore, public sector investment is the “adjustment variable” of spending to generate fiscal income (which is very procyclical). The volatility in this item is the result of the absence of countercyclical mechanisms in the remaining items of public spending, in a context in which tax burden had reached a point where it is difficult to impose any new increase.4

3 The Uruguayan budget bill is a five-year program (Presupuesto Quinquenal) with yearly revision bills (Rendición de Cuentas) proposed by the executive and approved by the legislature.

4 Besides having a very low investment rate, the volatility of public investment makes it even more inefficient.

State reform: The design and implementation of state reform programs in Uruguay were traditionally the responsibility of diverse public offices with overlapping functions and deficient coordination, and with an important lack of human, technical and financial resources. In addition, legal measures related to state reform resulting from the dealings between the Executive and the legislative branch used to be quite inflexible due to political safeguards, though the implementation of reform policy needed room for adjustment. This affected the quality and coherence of the measures finally implemented.

The process was modified in 1996 with the creation of an articulated proposal on state reform of the central administration. The strategy was to pass the essential legal framework to implement the programmed measures in Congress and to establish an institution responsible for implementing the program. This framework allowed the Executive to define some regulations by decree, which increased flexibility in policy implementation, but also increased the effectiveness of lobby groups to influence the final outcome.

Three aspects of the reform process must be noted. First, measures related to state reform that emerge from an interaction between the Executive and the legislature tend to be rigid due to political safeguards. This applies to hiring civil servants, setting public wage scales, firing employees, etc. Second, reform policy tends to be more volatile at the implementation stage because of greater executive discretion and a poor observability of this discretion. This process is influenced by the action of interest groups, which affect specific decisions in the implementation stage. Third, measures that can be implemented as expected are those tied to external enforcement mechanisms such as the conditionality of financial disbursements by the Inter-American Development Bank (IDB). In these cases, the IDB’s conditionality plays a role when aligned with the government’s goals, by providing ammunition for the government to weaken those who oppose reform. Nevertheless, when all aspects of the state reform process are considered, they do not comprise a coherent and predictable policy as a whole, and an overall rigidity remains.

2.2 Tentative Characterization of Policies in Uruguay

A brief overview of the main characteristics of economic policies in Uruguay suggests that the country is able to generate diverse kinds of results. First, some policies seem to be relatively stable and are the result of a long-term perspective, such as the commercial and financial openness of the country. While some debate existed prior to the early 1980s, it is unusual today

to find voices in the political arena demanding a “closing” of the economy in the commercial or financial sectors. Historical precedence also plays a role, since it is very difficult now to conceive of retreating from MERCOSUR or closing the financial sector of the economy after the respective advances in both arenas. Second, there are some areas in which policies are characterized by low volatility, but they tend to also be of low quality and to show important signs of inflexibility. These are policy areas in which there are very large institutional costs of making and changing policy decisions and in which rigidity is the price to be paid for political protection against future reversals. These areas include pension policies, some areas of state reform (civil servants’ wages and hiring mechanisms) and fiscal policies, among other examples. Third, some outcomes show volatility since they are not subject to specific policies with a long-run perspective, and they are affected by the result of other rigid policies. For example, public sector investments are the “adjustment variable” of global fiscal performance, which is plagued by inflexibilities in the rest of the items. Therefore, the variable associated with the evolution of the business cycle is the investment expenditure of the central administration and state-owned enterprises.

It would not be accurate to describe policies in Uruguay in only one generic fashion, since there are different types of outcomes. With one type, the absence of a commitment mechanism would make the policy outcome highly volatile (as suggested by the history of trade protection and financial opening and closing). External commitment devices associated with international agreements, combined with historical precedence, tends to limit the power of domestic interest groups. A second group of policies includes those that are highly rigid and are kept that way by the blocking power of interest groups combined with voting interests. Thus, what exists is a) an increase in the equilibrium by commitment devices in policies that otherwise would be highly volatile, and b) huge inflexibilities in areas that also would be highly volatile in the absence of rigidities. As for the third type of outcome, it must be noted that the volatility does not emerge from the interaction of political actors with opposing preferences, but is the result of the inability of the political system to set any fiscal responsibility rules to generate countercyclical spending behavior.

Additionally, the fact that the country generates different types of policies is consistent with the analytical framework, since the resulting political decisions do not depend solely on the political institutions but also on the transaction-cost characteristics of the different arenas. Not all

policy areas imply similar policy preferences, similar demands in terms of intertemporal exchanges, the same mix of political and social actors or the same need for external enforcement. Several factors distinguish policies in terms of their transaction-cost characteristics, especially those related to intertemporal political exchanges: (i) the constellation of political preferences, how close they are, how salient the specific issue is and, in general, what are the expected gains from the political conflict; (ii) the availability of external enforcement mechanisms, (iii) the subset of political actors and veto players, (iv) the relationship between policy design and policy implementation in each arena and, consequently, the role of the legislature and the Executive in the actual implementation of the specific policy, (v) the cost of implementing safeguards, etc.

The description mentioned above can be consistent with the Spiller and Tommasi (2003) analytical model. This constellation of policies can emerge from an institutional environment that does not facilitate intertemporal exchanges and cooperation. In the cases in which political preferences are convergent, the expected gains from political conflict are not significant. Two examples of this situation are related to the financial and commercial openness of the Uruguayan economy, particularly since the late 1980s and early 1990s. First, most of the actors are convinced that a small country like Uruguay has to be open to international financial markets, since it needs loans and foreign direct investment in the development process. Second, after Argentina and Brazil decided to engage in an integration process (MERCOSUR), Uruguay had no choice but to join them, since they are its two main trade partners and they have a significant impact on Uruguay’s exports, financial markets and tourism industry. Cooperation on these issues had to be feasible even under a relatively “weak” institutional framework, because of the convergence of political preferences. Additionally, external enforcement mechanisms could be available (conditionality with multilateral financial organizations, like the IMF and the World Bank, and the MERCOSUR agreement contained in the Asuncion Treaty of 1991). In the latter process, the strategy of “tying one’s hands” was very clear and the political system could advance in the commercial openness with a depth that not even the dictatorship could. Therefore, relatively stable policies are the result of similar political preferences and the ability to generate external enforcement mechanisms, even under a political framework that does not encourage cooperation in the long run.

In cases in which preferences diverge but the cost of implementing safeguards is relatively low, the emerging policies are rigid and of low quality. Policies related to enrolling,

hiring and paying civil servants are one example of this situation. Instead of having a flexible strategy for adjusting the size of the bureaucracy, incorporating civil servants into the budgetary payroll, hiring based on the needs of the state and the employees’ professional background, and remunerating employees according to their opportunity costs, the current policy is characterized by the prohibition of enrolling new civil servants in the budget, the virtual impossibility of firing them, rigid and incoherent wage scaling, and the belief that every new contract is suspicious because of some political abuse of the hiring mechanism. These rigidities emerge from the need for political safeguards.

Another example has to do with bankruptcy procedures. The main law governing them has not been significantly changed in the last seven decades, and the results in this policy area are very poor. The inflexible mechanisms and the weakness of the institutional framework encourage agents to solve the resolution of failed firms outside of the courts or other formal procedures.

In the public sector investment process, volatility is the logical result of an absence of stable and adaptable policies in the fiscal arena. Since almost all the rest of the items in the public spending side are basically rigid (social security, wages, debt repayment, and so on), the procyclicality of fiscal income and the variations in the access to financial markets have to be compensated for by the evolution of an “adjustment variable:” public investment. The only expected outcome is volatility. Decision-making in this area is essentially the responsibility of the Executive.5 Nevertheless, it worth noting again that this volatility is not the result of political conflict, but of an inability to set long-term rules for managing public spending.

In general, these policies show a visible lack of coordination and consistency, with very negative effects on investment in domestic markets. The low quality of these policies becomes clear when negative economic shocks occur. This is the case for most of the arenas dealing with the rules of the game related to property rights and contracts. This is also the result of a weak institutional environment in which interest groups encourage the myopia of the political system. In fact, in several areas the rules of the game are blurred and in other areas the rules are well defined but poorly enforced.

5 Although the Executive does not directly decide the amount to be invested in state-owned enterprises, it crucially affects the decision-making process via negotiations regarding the amount of profits to be transferred from these companies to the Ministry of Finance.

3. A Description of the Uruguayan Political Process

3.1 Formal Political Institutions

The Uruguayan Constitution mandates a presidential regime, though significantly different in some ways from the U.S. model. Indeed, the central feature of Uruguayan presidentialism is the strong influence that the Executive exerts on the policymaking process through different legal mechanisms of controlling the legislative process. Like many other cases in the region, Uruguayan presidents have important legislative powers such as total or item vetoes, the exclusive authority to initiate bills in strategic areas (budget or tax policy) and the ability to send urgent consideration laws, as well as non-legislative powers such as ministerial appointments and other key bureaucratic spots. In the long run, at least since 1930, the executive branch has gained substantive power vis-à-vis the legislative branch in successive constitutional reforms, including the last amendment endorsed in 1996.

Despite their institutional powers, most Uruguayan presidents since 1985 have been politically weak. This political weakness is the result of two different features associated with the party system and the partisan organization. On the one hand, the party system has exhibited an increasing level of fragmentation since 1971, and particularly since 1989, with three and a half parties (the fraction will be explained below).6 On the other hand, and perhaps more importantly, Uruguayan political parties are factionalized, which means that the number of actors and hypothetical agents at the bargaining process will be higher than that set by the system.78 The transition from a bipartisan system to a multiparty system has meant that most Uruguayan presidents since 1989 have been forced to negotiate coalition governments with opposition parties and factions. In other words, the multiparty system is the causal factor that explains the minority condition of most Uruguayan presidents and has facilitated the emergence of coalition governments from the 1990s onward (Chasquetti and Moraes, 2000). Given the

6 The Effective Number of Parliamentary Parties (on average) for the period 1942-1966 was 2.27, and was 3.0

7 for the period 1971-1999.

7 Like the cases of Italy, Japan and Colombia, Uruguayan parties are factionalized. However, unlike those cases, Uruguayan factions are institutionalized agents within parties and the whole political system. Both Italian and Japanese factions are “informal” actors within parties, since the electoral system does not promote or legally legitimize those agents. Uruguayan factions are a direct consequence of the electoral rules, and for that reason they tend to be stable agents within parties, with their own leaders and organizations (see Section 4.2).

8 It is important to note that Uruguayan political parties are one of (if not the most) institutionalized parties in the region (Mainwaring and Scully, 1995). However, because of the factionalized structure, presidents are only factional chiefs rather that party chiefs. Those factions are also highly institutionalized in the political process, but show higher levels of electoral volatility compared with the parties as a whole.

英国文科类专业申请的情况

免费澳洲、英国、新西兰留学咨询与办理 官网:https://www.360docs.net/doc/2018775306.html, 英国文科类专业申请的情况 随着2019年英国申请季的开始,选专业又成为我们面临的重大事情。今天我们主要帮助学生梳理一下英国文科类专业申请的情况。 英国文科类的专业主要包括:教育学、政治学、社会学和人类学、传媒等。教育学 顾名思义就是研究当老师的学问。英国大学教育学专业分支丰富,不仅有倾向于教学的分支,例如倾向于教学方法的分支, 主要培养教学这个方向。还有倾向于管理的分支。例如教育领导管理的分支。主要培养学校的行政管理人员。所以如果想去大学当辅导员的学生,可以考虑这个专业分支哦。 政治学

免费澳洲、英国、新西兰留学咨询与办理 官网:https://www.360docs.net/doc/2018775306.html, 顾名思义研究国家和国际政治的专业。英国大学政治学主要开设专业分支有政治理论、国际关系和公共政策等。这一类专业申请比较多的是国际关系,因为国际关系相对于政治学,学习内容更加具体。例如国际关系会关注国际安全、人权与公平正义、比较政治经济学等。申请该专业的优势在于不需要专业背景,一般接受转专业申请的学生。分数要求也不高,例如去年有一个学生来自福建师范大学,本科是传播学,82分。申请到曼彻斯特大学和伯明翰大学。对于条件比较普通 的学生,可以考虑这个专业。 近期有一个学生来自于上海师范大学天华学院,本科国际商务贸易专业,分数是77分,学生比较想去好学校,在推荐学校和专业时,首先从文科出发,相对于教育学和传媒,学生申请国际关系更能申请到比较到的学校。 传媒 传媒属于我们申请的热门专业之一。传媒主要包括新闻,电影,媒体和创意产业等专业。新闻专业要求比较高的写作水平,所以新闻专业不太好申请,除非写作功底比较好的同学可以尝试。电影专业分支比较适合本科专业就是电影专业,因为课程涉及到一些动画设计等课程。媒体类和创意产业属于大家选择比较多的分支,因为专业背景比较宽泛,雅思要求比较适中,一般都是总分要求6.5(6.0)。典型学校有利兹大学、诺丁汉大学、华威大学、格拉斯哥大学、谢菲尔德大学。如果条件比较适中的学生可以选择纽卡斯尔大学、莱斯特大学、东英吉利亚大学等。去年有一个三本的学生,均分为 83,本科就读汉语言文学专业,拿到了上述3个大学的offer 。 人类学和社会学

共同但有区别责任原则

题目:共同但有区别的责任原则在实施中的困境与对策姓名:罗珠玉、戴政

共同但有区别的责任原则在实施中的困境与对策 摘要:共同但有区别的责任原则作为国际环境法的一项基本原则,该原则的要求在实践中未能得到充分尊重与落实。笔者通过对该原则实施困境及原因的分析,寻求解决该原则的可行性办法。 关键词:共同但有区别的责任原则;实施困境;可行性办法

共同责任和区别责任组成了共同但有区别责任原则。二者之间相辅相成,密不可分。一方面各国不能以任何的借口而拒绝参与环境保护问题,这是每个国家的共同责任;另一方面,基于合理性而产生的区别责任,我们在对待共同责任的同时要给予发达国家与发展中国家差别待遇。只有当我们正确的理解二者关系时才能确保该原则的正确实施。实践中,该原则面对来自不同国家的阻力。 一、共同但有区别的责任原则的实施困境 发达国家有先进的技术与雄厚的资金,在各国订立国际公约之初,对发达国家明确规定了需向发展中国家提供环保技术的援助。可公约本身并未说明具体的援助方式,使发达国家有机可趁,利用市场操作以高价的方式向发展中国家提供商业性援助。而即使存在无偿性援助,实际数据也令人心寒,发展中国家适应气候变化每年所需的资金大约在 500 亿美元,而联合国的专门基金从发达国家筹集到的资金从 90 年代初至今总计只有 670 亿美元,发达国家对发展中国家的资金援助可见一斑,这也是共同但有区别责任难以落实的一个重要原因。 在发展中国家共同但有区别的责任原则的实施也受到了挑战。发展中国家的经济水平比较落后,他们没有先进的技术支撑他们在保证解决自己温饱问题的同时兼顾环境保护,而要想解决生存问题必须以牺牲坏境为代价。传统的经济发展技术、能源技术已经不能适应现代可持续发展的要求,尤其 21 世纪对各国高新技术提出了更高的要求,在环境治理方面也不例外。现在单纯的现有技术转让已经不能满足发展中国家环境治理的需要了,发达国家需要尽可能地多与发展中国家进行技术交流与合作,让发展中国家也成为高新技术开发的参与者,掌握自主的知识产权。 最后,为应对国际环境的问题而制定的众多国际公约,足以应对坚持和实施共同但有区别的责任原则。比如《人类环境宣言》、《联合国气候变化框架公约》、《联合国海洋法公约》、《京都议定书》······这些制定与签署的国际公约,不仅构成了世界环境保护国家合作的标准,而且也未共同但有区别责任作出了各种细化的规定。 二、共同但有区别的责任原则实施中存在困难的原因 美国曾以不符合本国的国家利益为由退出《京都议定书》,而各国对其只能进行谴责,因为国家享有主权原则,有权决定自己是否愿意加入某一国际公约。

论共同但有区别责任原则在我国的适用(改)

论共同但有区别责任原则在我国的适用 摘要: 文章在结合我国的具体国情的基础上,对我国进行环境污染防治过程中在环境保护法律中适用这一前沿的原则所具有的理论基础以及需要注意的问题进行了探讨。 关键词:京都议定书;共同但有区别责任原则;共同责任;区别责任 1 共同但有区别责任原则概述 共同但有区别责任原则是国际环境法中的一项基本原则。这一原则的产生主要是基于各国社会发展的历史对国际环境的影响及本国的实际承担能力。其核心思想是,在实现将大气中温室气体的浓度稳定在防止气候系统受到危险的人为干扰的水 平上这一目标过程中全球各国都负有共同的责任和义务,但是基于各国的历史发展 状况及现实承受能力,发达国家应该在这一过程中应该率先承担并且承担主要的责任。 1.1共同但有区别的责任原则主要包含以下两个基本要素: 1.1.1共同责任 共同责任的理论依据:全球的生态系统是一个不可分割的整体,环境问题具有全球性,解决全球环境问题需要所有国家的参与,每个国家都有责任。全球环保问题已经成为人类共同关注的焦点,而不只是某一个国家的国内立法问题。 共同责任的内容:许多关于环境与发展的国际文件中均有共同责任的规定。共同责任要求每个国家不论其大小、贫富等方面的区别,都对保护全球环境负有一份责任,都应当参加全球环境保护事业,都必须在保护和改善环境方面承担义务。基于共同责任,所有国家,尤其是发展中国家,都应该参与关于可持续发展的立法以及相关法律 的实施。许多现有的有关环境的国际法律文件没有发展中国家的参与。为了保护发展中国家的利益,有必要对相关文件进行修订,从而确保上述法律文件适用范围的广泛性。 1.1.2有区别的责任 有区别的责任的理论依据:有区别的责任的理论依据是公平原则。如果一个国家曾未经其他国家同意而不公平地对其进行利用而使其付出代价,那么受害国有权要

论共同但有区别责任原则

论共同但有区别责任原则 ——全球环境 徐博 (机械与汽车工程系机制2082班) 摘要:文章在结合我国的具体国情的基础上,对我国进行环境污染防治过程中在环境保护法律中适用这一前沿的原则所具有的理论基础以及需要注意的问题进行了探讨。 关键词:京都议定书;共同但有区别责任原则 一、共同但有区别责任原则的主要内容 《京都议定书》第一次设定了具有法律约束力的温气限排额度,是迄今为止国际社会承诺削减温气排放、遏制地球变暖的唯一一项国际公约。结合1994年3月生效的《联合国气候变化框架国际公约》的相关内容可知,共同但有区别责任原则主要内容包含两个方面——共同责任以及有区别责任。由于现实原因的限制或者说是从公平的角度考虑,发达国家和发展中国家在国际环境保护中所要承担的责任的范围、时间、方式、手段等方面是有差异的,从历史和现实的角度出发,对于各国的具体责任的确定,应当兼顾公平与效率,统筹考虑各种因素,在公平和效率之间做出适当的权衡取舍。保护和改善全球环境是全人类的共同利益所在,是世界各国的共同责任。这种共同责任主要体现在:基于“地区生态系统的整体性”,各国,不论其大小、贫富方面的差别都应该采取措施保护和改善其管辖范围内的环境,并防止对管辖范围以外的环境造成损害,同时各国应该在环境方面相互合作和支持等。但是另一方面,由于各国经济发展和工业化的水平不同,废弃物和污染物的排放数量也不同,不应该要求所有的国家承担完全相同的责任。发达国家在自身发展过程中曾经向大气排放大量有害物质,最先并且主要是他们造成了大气的污染,发展中国家不应为他们造成的大气污染后果承担责任。 二、共同但有区别责任原则适用于我国环境法律体系的基础 不可否认,共同但有区别责任原则在全球范围内是适用、且必须加以运用的。一种被证实具有优越性的原则能否在我国的环境法中适用,必须要针对我国的具体国情以及此原则的特征进行分析。 (一)我国在环境保护方面与世界进行了深入的交流和合作,具备运用相应知识的能力 从环境角度来看,世界是一体的,一国环境的污染和破坏都可能引起相关地区甚至全球范围内的环境破坏。我国积极参加全球范围内的环境保护活动,签订相关的环境保护国际协议。我国先后与30多个国家签署了双边环境合作协议或备忘录,与美国、日本、法国、德国、加拿大、俄罗斯等10个国家签订了有关核安全与辐射环境管理的双边合作协议,与联合国环境规划署、联合国开发计划署、国际原子能机构、世界银行、亚洲开发银行、全球环境基金、蒙特利尔议定书多边基金等国际机构建立了密切的合作关系。积极参与了重要国际环境公约的谈判和重要多边环境论坛的活动,参加或签署了气候变化框架公约、生物多样性公约、保护臭氧层的维也纳公约和蒙特利尔议定书、巴塞尔公约、核安全公约等国际环境公约,广泛、深入地开展了有关国际公约的履约工作。表明我国在环境保护方面已经全面与世界接轨,对国际环境保护及其责任履行上的原则有了深入地了解和学习,能够结合我国的具体实际情况合理地移植到我国的相关法律体系中来。

论国际环境法的共同但有区别责任原则

目录 毕业论文诚信承诺书 (2) 摘要 (3) 关键字 (3) 正文 一、共同但有区别责任原则的概述 (3) 二、共同但有区别责任原则的发展 (4) 三、共同但有区别责任原则的性质 (5) 四、共同但有区别责任原则的意义 (6) 五、坚持和发展“共同但有区别责任”原则 (6) 结语 (7) 参考文献 (7)

毕业论文诚信承诺书 本人作为《论国际环境法的共同但有区别责任》一文的作者,郑重承诺: 一、本论文是我在导师的指导下,参考相关文献资料,进行分析研究,独立完成的,其中所引用的文献资料和相关数据,都是真实的,除标明出处的内容外,不包含他人已公开发表的研究成果和学术观点。 二、本论文中若有抄袭他人研究成果和剽窃他人学术观点,本人自愿承担取消毕业论文成绩、交回学历学位证书等一切后果。 学生签名: 年月日注:本承诺书一式二份,一份置于毕业论文分册首页,一份置于过程材料分册末页。

论国际环境法的共同但有区别责任原则 摘要 环境保护已经成为我们时代最为重大的主题之一。世界每一个成员都应当共同承担保护和改善全球环境的责任,环境保护不再是仅限于一个两个国家主权之间的事情。全球性环境问题需要所有国家的共同努力才能得以解决。在对环境问题形成所起的作用上,发达国家和发展中国家扮演者主次不同的角色。如果要让本来就相对贫困的发展中国家在解决目前的全球性问题上承担和发达国家同样的义务,肯定是不公平的,必然会遭到发展中国家的反对。国际环境法的共同但有区别的责任原则“就在这样的背景下产生了,它调解了国家之间的矛盾,促进各国都参与到全球环保事业当中,将不同国情,制度的国家团结成一个“求大同、存小异”合作的整体。共同担有区别的责任原则主要包含两层意思:共同责任和区别责任。它不但是国际法上的一项重要原则,更代表了环境争议思想在适用范围上的扩展,本文主要探讨共同但是有区别的责任的定义、内涵以及环境正义与共同但有区别的责任之间的关系,还有共同但有区别的责任定义的必要性。 关键字 共同但有区别的责任国际发达国家发展中国家 一、共同但有区别责任原则的概述 国际环境法中共同但有区别责任原则因体现谋求优先发展经济的利益诉求,获得大部分发展中国家认同。但该原则的地位、内容一直存有争议。随着中国、印度等发展中大国碳排放日益增长,在后续气候谈判中如仅以发展中国家身份不参加实质减排,将面临极大压力。因此,探讨该原则的地位以及承担责任的依据,对于确定发达国家与发展中国家应对气候变化所应承担的共同责任以及各自应承担的义务,将具有重要意义. 共同但有区别责任主要体现在国际气候大会中表现最为明显,备受关注的联合国第十九次气候变化大会雨2013年11月23日晚在波兰首都华沙落幕,会期比原计划拖延了一整天。经过长达两周的艰难谈判和激烈争吵,特别是会议结束前最后48小时,各国代表挑灯夜战,最终就德班平台决议、气候资金和损失损害补偿机制等焦点议题签署了协议。 但是,由于发达国家不愿承担历史责任,在落实向发展中国家提供资金援助问题上没有诚信,导致政治互信缺失,加上个别发达国家的减排立场严重倒退,致使谈判数次陷入僵局。会议最终经过妥协,达成了各方都不满意、但都能够接受的结果。 《联合国气候变化框架公约》第十九次缔约方会议暨《京都议定书》第九次缔约方会议23日晚打破僵局达成协议后在华沙落下帷幕。尽管大会成果不尽如人意,但中方表示,节能减排是中国可持续发展的内在要求,无论谈判进展如何

“共同但有区别的责任”原则的解读

龙源期刊网 https://www.360docs.net/doc/2018775306.html, “共同但有区别的责任”原则的解读 作者:王小钢 来源:《中国人口·资源与环境》2010年第07期 摘要哥本哈根气候变化会议中最大的立场之争可能是关于“共同但有区别的责任”原则的政治辩论。“给不平等者以不平等”和“给平等者以平等”是“共同但有区别的责任”原则的哲学基础。历史责任、矫正正义和“与能力有关的责任”体现了“给不平等者以不平等”的理念。人均排放权和平等参与权则体现了“给平等者以平等”的理念。在“共同但有区别的责任”原则视域中,不是中国,而是丹麦和美国劫持了哥本哈根气候变化会议。从中国的立场看,国际社会在哥本哈根气候变化会议之后理应在“给不平等者以不平等”和“给平等者以平等”理念基础上坚守“共 同但有区别的责任”原则。首先,国际社会应将历史累积排放量和人均GDP作为适应气候变化的参考标准。其次,鉴于发展中国家的发展律令和后代人的正当需要,国际社会应将人均累积排放量和人均排放量作为减缓气候变化的参考标准。最后,国际社会必须按照平等参与原则开展将来的国际谈判。 关键词气候变化;共同但有区别的责任;给不平等者以不平等;历史责任:人均标准 中图分类号X22 文献标识码 A 文章编号1002-2104(2010)07-0031-07 doi:10.3969/j.issn.1002-2104.2010.07.005 2009年12月19日,哥本哈根气候变化会议落下帷幕。《联合国气候变化框架公约》(以下简称《公约》)各缔约方均不太满意,尽管缔约方会议同意“注意到”(taking note of)《哥本哈根协议》(Copenhagen Accord)。由于苏丹、委内瑞拉和玻利维亚等国家的反对,缔约方会议没有通过《哥本哈根协议》。在联合国条约中,“注意到”的术语意味着缔约方会议没有批准也没有通过,不持肯定态度也不持否定态度。哥本哈根会议中最大的立场之争可能是关于“共同但有区别的责任”(Common But Differentiated Responsibilities)原则的政治辩论。中国、印度、巴西和南非(BASIC四国)在多次谈判场合重申坚持“共同但有区别的责任”(Common But Differentiated Responsibilities)原则。然而,美国总统奥巴马(Barack Obama)甚至在12月18日领导人会议上发言将“共同但有区别的责任”修改为“共同但有区别的回应”(Common But Differentiated Responses)。在气候正义的视角下,全球气候体制中“共同但有区别的责任”原则的哲学基础究竟是什么?在“共同但有区别的责任”原则视域中,究竟是哪些国家劫持了哥本哈

武汉工程大学文科基金项目

所属学科及学科代码: 项目编号: 武汉工程大学文科基金项目 申请书 项目名称: 项目负责人: 联系电话: 依托学院部门: 申请日期: 武汉工程大学科技处制 2007年9月

简表填写要求 一、简表内容将输入计算机,必须认真填写,采用国家公布的标准简化汉 字。简表中学科(专业)代码按GB/T13745-92“学科分类与代码”表填写。 二、部分栏目填写要求: 项目名称——应确切反映研究内容,最多不超过25个汉字(包括标点符号)。 学科名称——申请项目所属的第二级或三级学科。 申请金额——以万元为单位,用阿拉伯数字表示,注意小数点。 起止年月——起始时间从申请的次年元月算起。 项目组其他主要成员——指在项目组内对学术思想、技术路线的制定理论分析及对项目的完成起主要作用的人员。

一、项目信息简表

二、选题:本课题国内外研究现状述评;选题的意义。 三、内容:本课题研究的基本思路和方法;主要观点。 四、预期价值:本课题理论创新程度或实际应用价值。 五、研究基础:课题负责人已有相关成果;主要参考文献。 六、完成项目的条件和保证:包括申请者和项目组主要成员业务简历、项目申请人和主要成员承担过的科研课题以及发表的论文;科研成果的社会评价;完成本课题的研究能力和时间保证;资料设备;科研手段。 (请分5部分逐项填写)。

七、经费预算

六、项目负责人承诺 我确认本申请书及附件内容真实、准确。如果获得资助,我将严格按照学校有关项目管理办法的规定,认真履行项目负责人职责,积极组织开展研究工作,合理安排研究经费,按时报送有关材料并接受检查。若申请书失实或在项目执行过程中违反有关科研项目管理办法规定,本人将承担全部责任。 负责人签字: 年月日 七、所在学院意见 负责人签字:学院盖章: 年月日 八、科技处审核 已经按照项目申报要求对项目申请人的资格及项目申请书内容进行了审核。项目如获资助,科技处将根据项目申请书内容,落实项目研究所需经费及其它条件;以保证项目按时顺利完成。 科技处盖章 年月日

论共同但有差别责任原则

黑龙江大学自学考试法律专业本科 毕业论文 题目:论共同但有差别责任原则作者:吴春刚 所在单位: 指导教师:李艳岩 黑龙江大学 2008年10月18日

目录 内容摘要 (1) 一、共同但有差别责任的体现 (1) 二、共同但有差别责任原则的内容 (2) 三、共同但有区别的责任原则的合理性分析 (2) 四、共同但有区别责任原则的正义基础 (3) (一)正义的一般含义 (3) (二)环境正义观念的起源 (4) (三)承担责任的实际能力分析 (4) 五、共同但有区别的责任原则在实践中的贯彻状况 (5) 六、落实共同但有差别责任原则的努力 (6) 七、结束语 (7) 参考文献 (9)

论共同但有差别责任原则 摘要:国际环境法是一个正在迅速发展的法学部门,国际环境法基本原则的体系也正在形成之中,共同但有差别责任原则的涵义分为共同的责任和有差别的责任,基于环境与人类的密切关系,在环境领域,全球所有国家对地球环境污染负有共同的防治责任,但是,由于历史的原因,发达国家只顾发展,不顾环境,大量使用环境资源和大量排放废弃物造成全球环境恶化,另发达国家在以全球环境资源的大量损耗和环境状况的急剧恶化为代价积累起来丰富的技术和财力资源,基于环境法的“谁破坏,谁治理”的公平原则,发达国家理应承担比发展中国家更为主要的或承担更多的义务。此原则在一系列国际环境法规中得到了体现。 关键词:国际环境法共同责任区别责任环境 一、共同但有差别责任的体现 保护和改善全球环境昰国际社会所要承担的共同义务。作为国际社会主要成员的各个国家,自然负有保护和改善环境的共同责任。1967年的《外层空间条约》和1971年的《禁止在海洋床底及其底土安置核武器和其他大规模毁灭性武器条约》都承认了人类对环境的“共同利益”,要实现共同利益必然要求各国承担共同责任。[1]1972年斯德哥尔摩《人类环境宣言》指出:“……保护和改善人类环境是关系到全世界各国人民的幸福和经济发展的重要问题,也是全世界各国人民的迫切希望和各国政府的责任。”关于“区别责任”,《人类环境宣言》指出:“在发展中国家中,环境问题大半是由于发展不足造成的。……因此,发展中国家必须致力于发展工作,牢记他们优先任务和保护及改善环境的必要”。1982年《内罗毕宣言》指出:“……发达国家及有能力这样做的国家,应协助受到环境失调影响的发展中国家,帮助他们处理最严重的环境问题。”《气候变化框架公约》的原则部分规定:“各缔约国应当在公平的基础上,并

202X美国留学文科专业申请建议.doc

202X美国留学文科专业申请建议 现在,去美国留学,文科专业比较容易申请一些,但是,美国的文科专业众多,该如何申请呢,下面来说说美国留学文科专业申请建议。 1、文科专业非常庞杂,常见专业有:语言类,新闻和传播,政治学,社会学,人类学,历史学,经济学,法学,教育学,心理学,建筑学,城市规划和景观设计,艺术类等。 2、若是英语专业,可以申请教育学,比如教育心理,TESOL,早期教育等;文学类,比如比较文学等;传媒类,公关,广告等;或者政治学、社会学、历史学。具体申请什么专业根据申请人的背景经历进行确定。中文和日语专业的可以申请东亚研究,有东亚研究设置的专业都是TOP50的学校,所以申请难度也是很大的。 3、美国的顶尖大学综合排名前30的学校里设置传播学院的并不多。因为传播学是后兴起的专业才有七、八十年的历史,很多老牌的学校他们排斥这样的新兴学科,所以他们不设置这样的学院,例如哈佛,耶鲁,牛津,剑桥等根本没有传播学校。有些学校虽然有传播学院或者有相关的专业但是规模一般也很小,有些学生甚至只招生本校的本科生。例如:斯坦福大学,传播学一直没有权威的专业排名,比较出名的学校有:哥伦比亚大学,纽约大学,但是这两个牛校都只设置新闻学院,并没有传播学研究。而且这两个学校的新闻类专业是属于那种超级牛人才能申请到的,一般在国内每年招生只有1-2个,甚至没有。总的来说新闻类专业申请难度很大。并且对申请人的英语及GRE成绩要求非常高,并且申请人最好有在央视,新华社,这样的背景才会比较有利。 4、政治学,社会学,人类学和历史,一般硕士的申请很难拿到奖学金,博士奖学金设置会很多,但是同时对学生的研究兴趣有要求,并希望看到学生对未来的职业发展规划。

试论国际环境法的共同但有区别责任原则

试论国际环境法的共同但有区别责任原则 试论国际环境法的共同但有区别责任原则 的国际责任。而另一方面发展中国家相比而言,发展起步较晚,工业化进程对全球环境的影响小,加之很多发展中国家还没有摆脱贫困的威胁,从某种意义上说发展是其的第一要义。同时发展中国家治理环境的资金技术匮乏,客观上也不具备彻底清除全球污染的实力。因此,区别责任强调,应对全球环境问题,发达国家和发展中国家的责任是有区别的,发达国家理应承担更多的、更重的责任。这也是“受益者补偿”原则的体现,同时也是维护实质正义的要求。 二、共同但有区别责任原则确立及发展 1.共同但有区别责任原则的确立。1972年在斯德哥尔摩召开的第一届人类环境大会,是国际社会就环境问题召开的第一次会议。在此次会议上通过的人类环境宣言,其内容强调和突出了利益和责任的共同性,以及具体环境和实际情况的区别,是共同但有区别责任的萌芽;1992年在巴西的里约热内卢召开的联合国环境与发展大会,是应对全球气候变化的一次会议。大会签署了《联合国气候变化框架公约》,会议提出“鉴于导致全球环境退化的各种不同因素,各国负有共同但有区别的责任”,这就正式提出了共同但有区别的责任原则,标志着共同但有区别原则的确立。根据此原则,发达国家应采取措施限制温室气体排放,同时要向发展中国家提供新的额外资金以支付发展中国家履行《公约》所需增加的费用,并采取一切可行的措施促进和方便有关技术转让的进行。 2.共同但有区别责任原则的发展。由于《联合国气候变化框架公约》没有对个别缔约方规定具体需承担的义务,也未规定实施机制,缺少法律上的约束力。因此,五年后以议定书的附属形式设定了强制排放的限制。1997年在日本京都,联合国气候变化框架公约的缔约方大会举行会议并通过了《京都议定书》,核心内容是:要求全球38个工业化程度较高的国家削减温室气体的排放量,规定了具体的减排义务。可见《京都议定书》遵循了公约确立的原则,规定了全球各国的二氧化碳排放量标准,但对发展中国家和发达国家的排放量的限制采用了双重标准,为遏制全球变暖发达国家应尽更多的义务。《京都议定书》规定的各国二氧化碳的排放标准截止到201X

高中理科申请书

篇一:高一文理分科申请表 高一文理分科申请表 明: 1、传 媒含播音与主持艺术、广播电视编导、服饰艺术与表演、影视表演、空中乘务等专业;美术含 绘画、书法艺术和书法教育、设计等专业;音乐含声乐、舞蹈、器乐、理论作曲、指挥等专业。 2、本 申请表经学生、家长、班主任签名后,不能再更改,学校以此为依据重新分班。 上梅 中学教务处 2013年12月28日 篇二:文理分科申请书 请书 敬的老师: 我 是,现在高()班,本人喜欢科技制作、科普读物、科技发明和生命科学等相关 知识与能力锻炼,对理科的兴趣大于对文科的兴趣。经过慎重考虑,并与家长商量,我决定申 请就读(文科、理科、美术、体育、音乐、舞蹈、传媒)班,敬请批准。 谢谢! (学 生本人签名)年月日 意上述申请。 (家 长签名)年月日 篇三:转班申请书 转班申请书尊敬的杨老师: 您好! 我想转到理科高二(16)班.因为经过假期的思考,我发现自己对文科没有很大的兴趣,而且

我也了解到自己在文科方面很难得到提高。对此,我恳请杨老师能让我转到理科高二(16) 班,我真切希望自己能转理科高二(16)班,我总结了我转班的原因,有以下几点: 一、 我觉得自己对文科的兴趣没有了之前的那种热情,而且我觉得自己在理科方面还有待提高,我 对它也很感兴趣。人们都说兴趣是学习最好的老师,有了兴趣就是成功的一半。而现在我对文 科已经没有了那种热情,又怎么会对学习文科尽心尽力、认真努力的去做呢?所以我真心的想 转到理科。 二、 我的文科成绩不是很好,而且从小我就贪玩把英语落下了很多。然而英语在文科当中可以占很 大的优势,我的英语很差,读文科没有优势,所以我希望自己能转到理科。 三、 学习文科需要很好的记忆力,但我这个人很赖,不喜欢背诵,而文科又需要背诵和 忆。 四、 根据社会的需求和我个人的发展空间,我想理科更适合我。 亡羊 补牢,为时不晚,希望杨老师能给我一次机会。 此致 敬礼 申请 人: 011年7月31日 篇四:申请书 尊敬的政府领导: 我叫 xxx,19xx年xx月xx日生,系xxx居民,配偶19xx年生,也是xxx人,我们都无固定 职业,现有家庭成员x人,家庭月收入xxx元。我们也曾经多次想买房子,但就我们这点收 入想买完全属于我们自己的房子那简直是奢望。所以本人和家人至今也一直居无定所,但为了 生活,又不得不在城区内四处奔波打工,并租房居住。由于本人家庭生活的实际困难和无住房 的实际情况,现想申请政府廉租住房一套,望领导给予批准为盼! 谢谢! 请人:

论共同但有区别责任原则

论共同但有区别责任原则 姓名:杜晓静 专业:国际法学 学号:09122326

论共同但有区别责任原则 摘要:共同但有区别责任原则勾勒出了发达国家和发展中国家在承担全球环境退化责任问题上的大致轮廓,在解决国际环境问题领域有着重要的作用。但该原则在实践的过程中也面临着重重挑战。本文介绍了该原则的历史发展,分析了它的内涵和合理性,最后结合其在国际环境法中的实践,对它的适用前景提出了设想。 关键词:共同但有区别责任国际环境法合理性

共同但有区别的责任原则是指由于地球生态系统的整体性和导致环境退化的各种不同因素,以及能力上的差异,各国对保护和改善全球环境负有共同的但是又有区别的责任。关于该项原则在国际环境法中的地位,一直存在着很大的争议。但毫无疑问,该原则在解决国际环境问题领域有着重要的作用,它勾勒出了发达国家和发展中国家在承担全球环境退化责任问题上的大致轮廓。 一、共同但有区别责任原则的历史发展 最开始,在国际环境保护领域只是强调“共同责任”。如1959年《南极条约》的序言指出:“……承认为了全人类的利益,南极应永远专为和平目的而使用,不应成为国际纷争的场所和对象”;又如1967年《外层空间条约》的序言指出:“……确认为了和平目的发展,探索利用外层空间,是全人类的共同利益”;1971年《拉姆萨尔湿地公约》的序言承认,“人类同其环境的相互依存关系”。[1]直到1972年《人类环境宣言》第一次将发达国家和发展中国家的环境问题区分了开来,被认为是该原则的萌芽阶段。它指出:“在发展国家中,环境问题大半是由于发展不足造成的。……因此,发展中国家必须致力于发展工作,牢记它们优先任务和保护及改善环境的必要,”“应筹集资金维护和改善环境,其中要照顾到发展中国家的情况和特殊性,照顾到它们的请求而额外的国际技术和财政援助的需要。”[2]文件虽然没有明确使用“区别责任”,但提到了要照顾发展中国家的情况和特殊性。 而1992年里约会议提出了“鉴于导致全球环境退化的各种不同因素,各国负有共同但有区别的责任”,从而确立了这一原则。1992年的《联合国气候框架公约》把发达国家置身于承担环境问题责任的前列,强调了这一原则。在《气候变化框架公约》第3条中明确提到了共同但有区别责任,“各缔约国应当在公平的基础上,并根据它们共同但又有区别的责任和能力,为人类当代和后代的利益保护气候系统。因此,发达国家缔约方应当率先对付气候变化及其不利影响。”这段话为“共同但有区别责任”指出了法理基础。 1997年《京都议定书》更是以“共同但有区别原则”为基础制定的,在国际实践中被誉为“共同而有区别原则”的典型代表。议定书明确规定了发达国家温室气体排放削减义务,发展中国家没有削减的义务。议定书中规定,在2008-2012年间,附件一国家应将其温室气体排放量从1990年的水平减少5%,并为这些国家规定了具体的减排指标;附件二国家是附件一国家中的工业化国家,除了承担减排义务外,还要为发展中国家提供新的额外资金,并向这些国家转移用于缓解和适应气候变化的先进技术;而发展中国家仅仅承担研究、报告、宣传、培训教育等一般义务,当然也可以自愿减排。[3] 共同但有区别责任原则被确立下来,并在国际环境法中被广泛的应用,它有着丰富而深刻的内涵。 二、共同但有区别责任原则的内涵 共同但有区别原则指,各国对保护全球负有共同的但是有区别的责任,包括共同责任和区别责任两方面。共同责任指国际社会的每个成员国不论大小、强弱,都有义务去保护地球环境。这一点很多国际环境条约上都得到了体现,如《生物多样性公约》确认了生物多样性保护是人类共同的关注事项。具体而言,共同责任可以从以下几个方面加以理解: (1)各国都有义务保护本国的环境。各国有责任采取有效的措施,通过制定一系列法规严格追究国内环境损害责任。 (2)各国有责任对该国管辖内的企业或个人的活动给他国造成环境损害承担

法国文科类专业留学指南 如何申请适合自己的文科类专业.doc

法国文科类专业留学指南如何申请适合自己的文科类专业法国的商科和理工科在世界范围内都是非常出色的,文科虽稍微逊色,但也是很出色的,今天就和的我一起看看法国文科类专业留学指南如何申请适合自己的文科类专业? 首先看看法国文科类专业留学有哪些优势? 法国文学在欧洲乃至世界文坛上都很有影响力,今年再次获得诺贝尔文学奖就是明证,但是如果你打算去法国读文学专业,那么实在是不大正确的选择。 任何一种文学需要本国本民族的人去学习才会比较顺手,而且一旦毕业之后也更容易获得专业认可。研究中国现当代文学的很少有西方学者,去法国读文学专业也同样如此。 而去法国学习法国历史和社科类专业也同样如此。当然这类专业显得很高大上,但本身就是些“十年一坐冷板凳”的专业,更何况是外国人去研究法国的历史社会情况,我想大多数学生是不会去选择这类专业的。事实上也是很少有学生去法国留学报考这类专业。 接着再来看看申请法国文科生专业要做好哪些准备? 1.合理选择专业,明确职业规划 法国公立学校原则上不允许学生自由转换专业,学生最好尽量申请跟自己国内专业相近或相关的专业,以避免专业跨度太大影响面签。而且法国学校非常重视学生的职业规划,建议学生申请时一定要明确自己未来计划学习的专业以及毕业后将要从事的领域,不能一味盲目追求热门专业,适合自己的才是最好的。 2.提前做好准备,语言学习充分 法国留学整个申请流程比较长,通常建议最好提前至少一年开始着手申请并开始学习法语,而且艺术设计类学校一般为全法语授课(只有少部分学校有英语授课项目),而且公立学校在法国读完语言后升专业对法语

要求相对较高,需要通过学校的考试。学好法语是保证顺利通过面签和顺利通过考试升学的必要条件。 最后再来看看法国有哪些好的文科类专业? 1.商学专业 法国大多数的商学院是独立于公立大学之外的。以前法国不少集团公司鉴于自己很难找到自己想要的实习生,因此就索性根据自己的需求成立了不少商业学院。 这样一来,对于学生来讲,理论和实践都能够结合起来。随着历史的发展,这类商学院毕业的学生能力普遍比较强,适合职场工作,因此很多法国公司甚至国际上的大型跨国公司都喜欢招聘这类商学院的毕业生。 其中,欧洲工商管理学院(INSEAD)、巴黎高等商学院(HEC)、法国著名高等学府(ESSEC)都是在国际上颇有声誉的法国商学院。像INSEAD是世界最大和最有影响力的独立商学院之一,也是欧洲最受尊重、历年排名首位的商学院。可以看到在文科专业之中,去法国留学就读这一方向的专业还是很有前途的。当然也需要注意,这类商学院的学费也比较高昂,INSEAD一年就要3-4万欧元,因此申请者需要较好的经济实力。 2.法学专业 学过法律的同学应该知道,现在我们国家的法系属于所谓的“大陆法系”。这里的“大陆”指的就是欧洲大陆。而欧洲大陆的法系的来源则是法国。 因此到法国学习法学专业,可以对于法律有更加清晰的了解和认知,更能接触到世界法学的原始样本和先进理念,其法学体系知识是非常完备的。 但是也要注意中国学生到法国去留学法学专业的话,难度会比较大。有个学生申请到法国里昂大学的法学院,可以说资质条件是非常好的,但是在那里学习的时候就曾反映,自己还是对于学习颇有些头疼。

文科主要科研项目申报信息汇总-推荐下载

主要文科科研项目申报信息 所属部委或单位:全国哲学社会科学规划办公室 所属部委或单位:国家自然科学基金委 、管路敷设技术弯扁度固定盒位置保护层防腐跨接地线弯曲半径标高等,要求技术交底。管线敷设技术包含线槽、管架等多项方式,、电气课件中调试核与校对图纸,编写复杂设备与装置高中资料试卷调试方案,编写重要设备高中资料试卷试验方案以及系统启动方案;对、电气设备调试高中资料试卷技术常高中资料试卷工况进行自动处理,尤其要避免错误高中资料试卷保护装置动作,并且拒绝动作,来避免不必要高中资

所属部委或单位:国家科技部 所属部委或单位:国家教育部 、管路敷设技术通过管线不仅可以解决吊顶层配置不规范高中资料试卷问题,而且可保障各类管路习题到位。在管路敷设过程中,要加强看护关于管路高中资料试卷连接管口处理高中资料试卷弯扁度固定盒位置保护层防腐跨接地线弯曲半径标高等,要求技术交底。管线敷设技术包含线槽、管架等多项方式,为解决高中语文电气课件中管壁薄、接口不严等问题,合理利用管线敷设技术。线缆敷设原则:在分线盒处,当不同电压回路交叉时,应采用金属隔板进行隔开处理;同一线槽内,强电回路须同时切断习题电源,线缆敷设完毕,要进行检查和检测处理。、电气课件中调试装过程中以及安装结束后进行 高中资料试卷调整试验;通电检查所有设备高中资料试卷相互作用与相互关系,根据生产工艺高中资料试卷要求,对电气设备进行空载与带负荷下高中资料试卷调控试验;对设备进行调整使其在正常工况下与过度工作下都可以正常工作;对于继电保护进行整核对定值,审核与校对图纸,编写复杂设备与装置高中资料试卷调试方案,编写重要设备高中资料试卷试验方案以及系统启动方案;对整套启动过程中高中资料试卷电气设备进行调试工作并且进行过关运行高中资料试卷技术指导。对于调试过程中高中资料试卷技术问题,作为调试人员,需要在事前掌握图纸资料、设备制造厂家出具高中资料试卷试验报告与相关技术资料,并且了解现场设备高中资料试卷布置情况与有关高中资料试卷电气系统接线等情况,然后根据规范与规程规定,制定设备调试高中、电气设备调试高中资料试卷技术电力保护装置调试技术,电力保护高中资料试卷配置技术是指机组在进行继电保护高中资料试卷总体配置时,需要在最大限度内来确保机组高中资料试卷安全,并且尽可能地缩小故障高中资料试卷破坏范围,或者对某些异常高中资料试卷工况进行自动处理,尤其要避免错误高中资料试卷保护装置动作,并且拒绝动作,来避免不必要高中资料试卷突然停机。因此,电力高中资料试卷保护装置调试技术,要求电力保护装置做到准确灵活。对于差动保护装置高中资料试卷调试技术是指发电机一变压器组在发生内部故障时,需要进行外部电源高中资料试卷切除从而采用高中资料试卷主要保护装置。

文科生申请日本留学的条件.doc

文科生申请日本留学的条件 现在,的女生比较多,一般女孩子选择文科会多一些,那文科生寻求自身更好地发展选择去日本留学申请条件是什么满足什么条件才可以申请?有什么专业可以选择?今天就来说说文科生申请日本留学的条件! 文科生去日本留学 文科生留学日本费用 日本留学性价比很高,它有着高水平教学质量,和较为亲民学费。 日本国公立大学学费 本科:53.5万日元/年约3万人民币 研究生:17万日元/半年约1万人民币 修士:53.5万日元/年约3万人民币 日本私立大学学费较国公立大学要高一些,文科相关专业学费大致如下: 本科:约70-90万日元约4-6万人民币 修士:约100-140万日元约6-8.4万人民币 另外日本设有各类奖学金,可以为同学们减轻一部分经济压力。 日本文科专业录取分析 出身校 日本文科对于学生背景学校没有明确限制。但是985、211背景出身学生申请前五名大学成功率则大很多,尤其是京都大学非常喜欢招收国内985、211院校学生。 语言要求 申请日本文科学校语言成绩非常重要,除获得日语成绩学生占绝大部分优势外,如果能掌握非常流利英语能力也很具有竞争优势。

专业背景 本专业申请和跨专业申请基本持平,但还是本专业申请学生占据优势。文科跨专业一般多是指日语专业同学选择其他专业继续攻读。 最为常见是攻读教育学和社会学,因为比起商科专业对专业出身要求低一些;也有一部分英语好日语专业学生转去研究国际关系或国际协力;也有一部分经贸日语专业学生成功申请到商科专业。 当然还有一部分日语专业学生选择继续本专业进学,多会选择研究日本语教育、日本文化或文学。 文科生留学日本读研基本条件 研究生(修士预科) 学历: 16年教育经历,大学本科生,拥有学士学位或专升本、自学考试学位取得者(可申请修士研究生);只有个别学校接受专科生,基本需要进行申请资格审查。 语言能力: 申请日本研究生一般来说文科专业日语水平需N1,N2也可,当然日语水平越高对申请会约有利。 修士 学历: 受过16年正规学校教育、具有本科毕业证和学士学位证者或受过15年教育专科生,但是需要资格审查,可以选择学校较少。 语言能力: 日语,根据大学、学科具体要求不同。有要求提供日语能力证明,有需要通过面试来判断是否达到可以满足研究需求语言水准。

美国文科研究生留学申请要求

美国文科研究生留学申请要求 美国文科研究生留学申请要求 1、背景要求: 专业要求美国文科专业申请对于申请者的专业背景要求各不相同,其中有对专业背景要求不高的传媒、教育等专业,也包括法律、国际关系、政治学等要求相关专业背景的学生才能申请的专业。 2、GPA要求:3.5+ 平均成绩要求美国文科申请虽然在中国的申请者之中不属于热门的方向,但美国文科专业会有更多的美国本土学生申请,所以一个很好的平均绩点都成为申请者强有力的竞争条件。对申请者平均分的要求一般都在3.0以上,对于法律、传媒这种相对热门的专业,或者国际关系、政治学等这种美国学生居多的专业,希望申请者的绩点能达到3.5以上。 3、语言要求:(托福\雅思\RE\) 语言要求由于文科的学习一向对语言的要求较高,另外牵扯到语言文化的不同,因此美国文科申请对于国际学生的语言要求普遍非常高,其中哥伦比亚大学、南加州大学的传媒专业甚至对申请者列出托福114分高标准。与此同时,多数美国文科强校都集中在50院校之中,因此变相提高了语言的要求。对于申请美国文科的申请者而言,建议着重于托福与GRE的Verbal部分,希望能达到至少100分托福加155分以上的GREVerbal的成绩。 扩展阅读:美国研究生留学的教育体制 美国的研究生向来都很高水平,对于研究生的要求也非常的严。也是因为这样,很多学生觉得要到美国的研究生院里去读肯定很难,其实它的门槛真的没有大家想象的那么高。如果的美国研究生已经不是从前那种精英教育,已经是非常普及的了。这是有数据可以看的,美国很多的大学中,研究生和本科生能保持1∶

1的比例,甚至有一些学校的研究生比本科生还多。 研究生主要是为了培养水平更高的人才。所以很多国家对于研究生的招收都会考察学生专业的知识掌握得如何。但是在美国这里的研究生招收,却不会对学生的专业基础有太多的考察。他们在招收硕士的时候都是用通用考试,主要是为了看学生有怎样的培养潜力。比如像是GRE这个考试是为了考查学生对于英语、数学等等方面的应用,就算是商学院必须要考的GMAT都不会有专业基础的内容。 要想进入研究生院确实不难,不过这不代表大家在申请到了之后就能不用想别的了。美国对于研究生们的要求还是很严的,学业上有非常重的负担。老师并不因为学生对于课程都是零起点就放慢教学进度,在这里,一个星期的课程内容就等同于本科一两个月的内容。此外老师还会让学生在课外做大量的阅读以及经常让学生写论文。 美国这边对于学位的规定是,只允许学生在得到学士学位后再去读研究生的学位。在学位体制上,美国采用的是五级制,而硕士的学位就有两种:一种要写论文,一种不需要写,不过学分就要求得比较高了。 而且在硕士学位上还有两种分类,就是文理科以及专业的硕士。文理科一般学分都需要要到24-30这个阶段,不过大多都是本专业的课程。专业硕士就有很明确的=定义了,会在学生的学位头衔前标明这个学生学的专业,而且这一类的课程会设置得非常紧凑,当然了,这些课程的声誉也较高。 美国在奖学金上也有很多种类,光是一个高校奖学金都能有服务性、非服务性以及贷款等等几种类别。不过美国大部分的高校都是会设置前两种奖学金给学生。虽然说此类资助不一定能包含学生一年中的费用,不过基本都能包含了2/3以上的费用。

参加高考申请书范文(精选多篇)

参加高考申请书(精选多篇) 参加申请书 申请人:______无线电元件二厂,地址:______市______路______号。法定代表人:李______,厂长。 委托代理人:刘______,男,____岁,______无线电元件二厂工程师,住本厂宿舍楼___号。 申请目的:参加诉讼。 申请理由:在______百货公司诉______无线电厂购销合同质量纠纷一案中,______百货公司声称因______无线电厂所产______牌收机录质量问题,造成了商品积压,影响了资金周转,要求赔偿损失。______无线电厂则声言我厂所产元件质量“不过关”造成的。 我厂是50年代组建的老厂家,所产______电子元件一直符合国家规定标准。______无线电厂所购该批电子原件,经______省质量检验中心检验,完全合格(见该批电子原件的质量鉴定书)。 我们认为,______无线电厂所产该批______牌收录机的质量问题,不是我厂______电子原件的问题,而是电子线路或其他技术方面的问题。此案既然涉及到我厂,其审理结果可能与我们有利害关系。为了不使我厂的合法权益遭受损失,根据《民事诉讼法》第五十六条第二款的规定,特申请参加本案的诉讼,望予批准。 此致

______人民法院 写给即将参加高考的你 写给即将参加高考的你。特别是,艺考生们! 看看时间,已经是2014年的5月7日的凌晨。我突然意识到:再过一个月,又将是一年一度的高考了!我心猛抽了一下,因为在若干年前的这个时候,我在家乡的某一所复读学校破旧的寝室里,正辗转难眠。 那个时候的我和你们一样,心怀梦想,却为自己能否顺利通过文化课而担忧。我几乎无法用语言来表达我当时内心的惶恐和压力,因为那时候我虽拿到了中戏的专业考试合格证,但那也只是仅有的一张,而那时候我已经21岁了!我知道,上天不会再给我一次机会的。 我的经历与现在电脑面前的你们不一样,你们大部分是应届生,顶多也只是复读一年或是两年。而我是从部队退役之后重新走入了复读学校,况且是在周围人群中除了我母亲以外所有人都怀疑、笑话、嘲笑我的举措之下的环境中做出的举动。记得退役之后的第一次月考,总分750分的试卷我只考了150多分,而那已经是当年的11月份,也就是说我除了要参加艺术考试的2个多月,仅有不到4个月的文化学习时间给我。被逼无奈我只有硬着头皮冲上前去。虽然说专业考试我顺利过了关,但中戏总分420分以上的录取线,外加语文90、外语70的单科小分对我来说依然是难以攻克的难题。

相关文档
最新文档