2030年中国经济:建设现代、和谐、有创造力的高收入社会

2030年中国经济:建设现代、和谐、有创造力的高收入社会
2030年中国经济:建设现代、和谐、有创造力的高收入社会

Part I

Overview

China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative High-Income Society

China 2030: Building a Modern, Harmonious, and Creative High-Income Society

From the early 1500s until the early 1800s, China’s economy was the world’s largest. By 1820, it was one-fifth again as big as Europe’s and accounted for a third of world gross domestic product (GDP). But the next two centuries were tumultuous for China. The country experienced catastrophic decline between 1820 and 1950 and then, starting in 1978, meteoric rise (Maddison 2001). Today, China is once again among the largest economies of the world, having overtaken Japan in 2010. Its economy is now second only to that of the United States (third, if the European Union is counted as one economy), and it is the world’s largest manufacturer and exporter. The East Asian miracle may have lost some of its luster after the financial crisis of 1997–98, but China’s performance continues to impress. Even if China grows a third as slowly in the future compared with its past (6.6 percent a year on average compared with 9.9 percent over the past 30 years), it will become a high-income country sometime before 2030 and outstrip the United States in economic size (its per capita income, however, will still be a frac-tion of that in advanced countries). If China achieves this milestone, it will have avoided the “middle-income trap” by traversing the seemingly impossible chasm between low-income and high-income status within a gen-eration and a half—a remarkable achieve-ment for any country, let alone one the size of China.

But two questions arise. C an C hina’s growth rate still be among the highest in the world even if it slows from its current pace? And can it maintain this rapid growth with

little disruption to the world, the environ-

ment, and the fabric of its own society? We

answer “yes” to both, but only if China tran-

sitions from policies that served it so well in

the past to ones that address the very differ-

ent challenges of a very different future.

This overview, supported by five under-

pinning volumes, identifies these challenges

of tomorrow, points to key choices ahead,

and recommends not just “what” needs

to be reformed, but “how” to undertake

the reforms. The overview is divided into

nine chapters.The first chapter examines

the characteristics of China’s development

since 1978; considers future opportuni-

ties, challenges, and risks; and describes a

vision of China in the year 2030. The sec-

ond chapter maps a new strategy that will

realize this vision, focusing on the key

choices ahead for C hina to sustain rapid

economic and social development and

become a modern, harmonious, and cre-

ative high-income society before 2030.

Chapters 3–8 elaborate on each of the six

p illars of the new strategy: consolidating

C hina’s market foundations; enhancing innovation; promoting green development;

ensuring equality of opportunity and social

protection for all; strengthening public

finances; and achieving mutually benefi-

cial win-win relations between China and

the rest of the world. The ninth and final

chapter addresses implementation chal-

lenges, including the sequencing of proposed

reforms and overcoming obstacles that are

likely to emerge.

c h i n a2030 3

Introduction

4 c h i n a2030

Unique factors behind China’s economic success

Over the past three decades, China’s two his-toric transformations, from a rural, agricul-tural society to an urban, industrial one, and from a command economy to a market-based one, have combined to yield spectacular results. Not only did economic growth soar, but the poverty rate fell from more than 65 percent to less than 10 percent as some 500 million people were lifted out of poverty, and all the Millennium Development Goals have been reached or are within reach. Although growth rates differed across China, growth was rapid everywhere. Indeed, if mainland China’s 31 provinces were regarded as inde-pendent economies,1 they would be among the 32 fastest-growing economies in the world (figure 1). Such rapid growth has been accompanied by many other achievements: for example, 2 of the world’s top 10 banks are now Chinese;2 61 Chinese companies are on the Global Fortune 500 list;3 and China is home to the world’s second-largest highway network, the world’s 3 longest sea bridges, and 6 of the world’s 10 largest container ports.4 The country has also made large strides in health, education, science, and technology, and is quickly closing the gap on all these fronts with global leaders.

Many unique factors lie behind China’s impressive growth record, including the initial conditions of the economy in 1978 that made it particularly ripe for change. The spark came in the form of agricultural reforms, including the household responsi-bility system that foreshadowed sustained reforms in this and other areas over the next 30 years. To summarize, key features of the reforms included:

Pragmatic and effective market-oriented reforms. China’s uniqueness among devel-oping countries is not what it did to achieve success, but how it did it. China adapted a strategy known as “crossing the river by feel-ing stones,” which encouraged local govern-ments to undertake bold pilot experiments. By introducing market-oriented reforms in a gradual, experimental way and by pro-viding incentives for local governments, the country was able to discover workable tran-sitional institutions at each stage of develop-ment. One key feature of these reforms was their “dual-track” nature—supporting state-owned firms in old priority sectors while lib-eralizing and encouraging the development of private enterprises (Lin 2012). The economy was allowed to “grow out of the plan” until the administered material planning system gradually withered. As a result of continuous and decentralized trial-by-error exploration, institutional arrangements evolved as new and different challenges needed resolution. Indeed, different localities often adopted their own unique institutions tailored to their specific situations.

Balancing growth with social and macro-economic stability.The difficult economic situation at the start of reforms in 1978 made economic growth an urgent priority. Early reform successes quickly transformed this priority into a national objective that was effectively used to mobilize all quarters of society—individuals and firms as well as local governments—to focus their collective efforts on economic development. The gov-ernment employed a mix of fiscal, adminis-trative, and employment policies to maintain social stability during a period of rapid eco-nomic and structural change. This was no mean achievement, given the need to employ an additional 9 million new entrants into the labor force each year while also absorbing workers affected by policy shifts (such as the 1998 reforms of state-owned enterprises, or SOEs), frictional unemployment, and occa-sional external economic shocks.

Rapid growth and structural change also presented macroeconomic challenges. The economy experienced occasional bouts of serious inflation, such as in the late 1980s and early 1990s. But macroeconomic stabil-ity was effectively restored through a com-bination of traditional monetary and fiscal policies, as well as administrative means

Chapter 1 China’s Path: 1978 to 2030

o v e r v i e w5 FIgUre 1 China’s impressive economic performance

Source: NBSC 2010; World Bank 2011b. Source: UNSD 2010.

when necessary. As a result, the authorities were broadly successful in keep-ing inflation low throughout the period and protecting the rural and urban poor from relative price increases in key necessities. Interregional competition.China built on its strong local governments at various lev-els by allowing them to compete in attract-ing investment, developing infrastructure, and improving the local business environ-ment. Decentralization policies, including fiscal reforms in 1994 (which significantly increased resource transfers from the cen-tral government), gave subnational govern-ments the incentives and the resources to aggressively pursue local development objec-tives. Increased factor mobility meant that resources flowed to jurisdictions most sup-portive of growth. Finally, China’s vast size and regional differences meant that local governments could experiment with and champion specific reforms suited to their circumstances, while operating within the parameters established by central authori-ties. Officials were rewarded for deliver-ing key reform goals: growth, foreign direct investment (FDI), employment, and social stability. The resulting competition between local governments and regions was fierce—and became a strong driver of growth—far beyond the expectations of the authorities. Domestic market integration.A key ele-ment of the reforms was the dismantling of regional barriers to the movement of goods, labor, and capital and the establishment of a single national market. Major infrastruc-ture investments connecting regions and the interior to the coast helped. A large and integrated domestic market allowed firms to achieve scale economies, and the large

6 c h i n a2030

variation in income levels and consumption patterns across the country gave their prod-ucts a longer life cycle.

Steady integration with the global econ-omy. With the establishment of special economic zones, Deng Xiaoping’s remarks during his famous South China tour, and accession into the World Trade Organiza-tion (WTO) as milestones, China expanded and deepened its economic integration with the global economy. This policy reaped large dividends for China, bringing investments, advanced technologies, and managerial expertise; opening the international market for China’s goods and services; and giving a boost to China’s internal economic reforms. The proximity of Hong Kong SAR, China, and Taiwan, China, helped, as did a large Chinese diaspora dispersed across the globe. Trends and characteristics at home and abroad in the

next two decades

China’s reforms, still ongoing, have facili-tated regional concentration of activities and captured agglomeration economies in coastal provinces, encouraged mobility of factors and goods across provinces and with the rest of the world, and established a high savings- and investment-led growth process disciplined by the competitive pressures of globalization. Most important, China has avoided economic setbacks: not only did economic growth average nearly 10 percent over more than three decades, it fell measur-ably below 8 percent only twice. During the recent global financial crisis, China’s contin-ued rapid growth was a significant stabilizing force that partly counterbalanced the impact on global economic activity of the down-turn and subsequent tepid recovery in the advanced economies.

Will China be able to sustain this per-formance over the next two decades? Much depends on how the global environment evolves and on the structural forces that are already at work within China. But this much is certain: trends at home and abroad will be very different over the next 20 years compared with the past 30, not only because China and other emerging markets have fun-damentally reshaped the global economy—a trend that was accelerated by the recent global financial crisis—but also because new global challenges and opportunities are emerging that will significantly affect the future trajectory of the world’s economies. global megatrends

The last three decades saw a supportive global environment that undoubtedly assisted and accommodated China’s rapid growth. Key elements included relatively open trade, rising flows of foreign direct investment, steady growth in the world’s major markets, sharply declining transport costs, increased intraindustry trade, and the introduction and spread of information and communica-tions technology. While extrapolating lin-early from the past may be dangerous, some of these trends are indeed likely to persist.5 There is widespread consensus, for example, that in addition to China, other developing countries, especially middle-income emerg-ing markets, will continue to outperform the advanced economies as they have for the past decade. One reason is their continued poten-tial for technological catch-up. The other is continued slow growth in advanced econo-mies owing to deleveraging and the impact of high sovereign debt burdens. By 2030, developing countries are expected to contrib-ute two-thirds of global growth (40 percent, excluding China) and half of global output (30 percent, excluding China), and will be the main destinations of world trade. The larger emerging markets—China more so than oth-ers—will act as additional growth poles in a multipolar world economy.

Perhaps the most important global mega-trend is the rise of China itself. No other coun-try is poised to have as much impact on the global economy over the next two decades. Even if China’s growth rate slows as pro-jected, it would still replace the United States as the world’s largest economy by 2030, its share in world trade could be twice as high, it is likely to remain the world’s biggest emit-ter of carbon dioxide, and, notwithstanding shrinkage in its trade surplus, it is expected

o v e r v i e w7

to remain the world’s largest creditor. Some have argued that by 2030 China’s influence in the global economy could approach that of the United Kingdom in 1870 or the United States in 1945 (Subramanian 2011).

C ontinued rapid growth in emerging markets will give rise to an unprecedented expansion of the global middle class (by one estimate, from less than 1.8 billion peo-ple in 2009 to about 5 billion in 2030, of whom nearly two-thirds will be in Asia).6 That expansion will trigger an explosion in demand for housing and consumer durables, including automobiles. The pressure on global supplies of energy, natural resources, food, water, and the environment will ratchet up rapidly. C limate change effects could exacerbate food and water shortages in some areas. The price of raw materials will remain elevated and volatile. Higher prices for scarce natural resources highlight the need to intro-duce “green growth” strategies that could potentially become a new source of growth.

Notwithstanding the potential for rapid growth in emerging markets, there are also reasons to believe that growth in developing countries, including China, will slow. First, as populations age, the growth rate of the labor force will slow, and in some countries (such as China and the Russian Federation) will even decline, leading to higher dependency ratios and lower savings and investment. Sec-ond, although emerging market economies will retain a comparative advantage in manu-facturing, rising unit labor costs will further increase their relative share of services; over-all growth would thus slow because produc-tivity growth in services is usually lower than in manufacturing.

While protectionism may occasionally rear its head, especially in advanced coun-tries where the impact of the recent financial crisis has been particularly severe, the forces of globalization will remain irresistible, and further cross-border movements of goods, services, finance, people, and knowledge will endure and deepen. Production chains across borders will continue to flourish, and intrain-dustry and intrafirm trade will intensify.

As global trade continues to grow at a more rapid rate than GDP, the new fron-tier will be trade in services, now the fastest-growing component of global trade. Thanks to new informational technologies, services previously considered nontradable (such as health and education) will be rou-tinely provided across national borders just as manufactures are now. In addition, the world is continuing to see further global relocation of industries (and, increasingly, tasks within industries) in the incessant search for global competitiveness.

The number of free trade arrangements in the world has multiplied manifold over the past two decades; over the next two, trade integration will intensify and production net-works will expand further. Intra–East Asian trade could rival that of intra-European trade (as a share of GDP). Emerging markets will develop an increasing stake in an open global trading system. The resolution of climate change, international financial stability, inter-national migration, health pandemics, water management, and other global challenges will require new approaches to transnational and global governance arrangements.

The U.S. dollar will likely remain the world’s major international reserve currency, especially given weaknesses in the Euro Area and Japan. But expansionary monetary poli-cies in the advanced countries, including the United States, will cause instability in the international monetary system, and uncer-tainty in key exchange rates will add to costs of international monetary and trade transac-tions. China’s growing weight in world trade, the size of its economy, and its role as the world’s largest creditor will make the interna-tionalization of China’s renminbi inevitable, but its acceptance as a major global reserve currency will depend on the pace and success of financial sector reforms and the opening of its external capital account (see chapter 8).

Technological breakthroughs, unpredict-able as they may be, are more likely in some areas, such as clean water, energy storage, and biotechnologies, than in others. A break-through in clean coal technologies would give China an obvious advantage, given its huge coal reserves. Renewable energy tech-nologies could also become more economi-cally viable. The recent pattern has been for such technological breakthroughs to occur in advanced countries, with their application

8 c h i n a2030

in commercial and mass production usually transferred to developing countries. This pat-tern is likely to continue; adoption, adapta-tion, and mastery of existing technologies will remain an important growth driver in developing countries. At the same time, how-ever, as emerging markets develop their own technological capability, new and disruptive technologies will appear in the developing world and raise the chance of “leapfrogging” over advanced countries in a few areas. Major trends within China

Just as growth is expected to slow in some emerging markets over the coming two decades, many signs point to a growth slow-down in China as well. Indeed, we expect GDP growth to decline gradually from an average near 8.5 percent in 2011–15 to around 5 percent in 2026–30 (see table 1). One rea-son for the slowdown is that much of the growth contribution from shifting resources from agriculture to industry has already occurred. And going forward, the continued accumulation of capital, although sizable, will inevitably contribute less to growth as the capital-labor ratio rises (even though capi-tal stock per worker, now an estimated 8.7 percent of the U.S. level, underscores the need for further capital accumulation). Moreover, C hina is poised to go through wrenching demographic change: the old age dependency ratio will double in the next two decades, reaching the current level in Norway and the Netherlands by 2030 (between 22 and 23 percent);7 and the size of China’s labor force is projected to start shrinking as soon as 2015. Yet workers will become more produc-tive as physical and human capital stock per worker continues to rise. Finally, total fac-tor productivity (TFP) growth—a measure of improvements in economic efficiency and technological progress—has also declined, in part because the economy has exhausted gains from first-generation policy reforms and the absorption of imported technologies. As a result, the distance to the technological frontier has shrunk, and second-generation policy reforms are likely to have a smaller impact on growth.8

These factors, together with “rebalanc-ing” policies to emphasize domestic growth sources, will contribute to a higher share of services and consumption in the economy and a lower share of exports, savings, and investment. The challenge will be to support these growth and structural transitions while avoiding sudden slowdowns and possible crises.

China’s external accounts are expected to show a decline in the trade surplus—export growth will slow as China’s global market share rises and markets in advanced coun-tries grow more slowly, while import growth will be driven by continued expansion in domestic demand. At the same time, how-ever, the external capital account will show a rising deficit as Chinese savings flow abroad in search of better returns and to counter protectionist pressures abroad. This trend will serve not only to keep in check further accumulation of external reserves but also to facilitate the transformation of Chinese enterprises into global players.

China’s current pattern of development has also placed considerable stress on the environment—land, air, and water—and has imposed increased pressure on the avail-ability of natural resources. The challenge going forward will be to convert these pres-sures into new sources of growth by adopt-ing a green growth model that taps into new global markets in green technologies while at the same time solving many of China’s own pressing environmental concerns. If success-ful, the energy and commodity intensity of production is expected to decline signifi-cantly by 2030 for three reasons: a smaller share of industry in GDP; a smaller share of resource- and pollution-intensive firms in the industrial sector; and better pricing of energy, commodities, and environmental services (see chapter 5).

Income inequality in China, which climbed continuously over the past two decades, is showing some tentative signs of beginning to flatten and possibly even decline. In the coming decades, three underlying structural factors could serve to confirm this inflexion point. First, acceleration of growth in the middle and western regions will continue,

o v e r v i e w 9so the income gap between the coast and the

interior will narrow. Second, migrant wages

will continue to rise rapidly, reducing the

income gap with urban residents. The role

of policy will be to support these structural

forces by increasing the equality of opportu-

nity (see chapter 6). Third, even though the

urbanization rate is expected to continue its

rise, rural-urban migration will gradually

slow over the period as the structural shift

from agriculture to manufacturing eases,

and the rural-urban wage gap narrows (the

urban-rural income ratio is expected to fall

from 3.2 : 1 in 2010 to 2.4 : 1 in 2030).

At the same time, rising educational stan-

dards and brisk growth in tertiary education

is rapidly increasing the numbers of skilled

workers and helping China move up the value

chain, and this process is likely to accelerate

in coming decades. The growing skill base

will facilitate a further shift in production

from labor-intensive to skill-intensive activi-

ties and an increase in the pace of innova-

tion. Indeed, just as in the 1980s and 1990s

when hundreds of millions of unskilled Chi-

nese workers joined the global labor force

as part of China’s “opening up” strategy, so

too will tens of millions of tertiary-educated

Chinese workers join the global workforce

to significantly expand the global supply of

skill-intensive products. Indeed, the number

of college graduates could swell by 200 mil-

lion over the next two decades—more than

the entire labor force of the United States.9At the same time, China’s existing com-parative advantage in low unit labor costs will shrink gradually. Rapidly rising real wages for unskilled workers in coastal prov-inces are encouraging firms to relocate to neighboring interior provinces where labor and land are more plentiful and relatively cheap. Thanks to continuous improvements in connective infrastructure between the interior and major cities and ports, the incre-mental transport costs from interior locations will be outweighed by the benefits of lower input costs.The rise in wages associated with increased productivity will continue to spur rapid expansion in the ranks of the middle class, which, in turn, will increase consump-tion of consumer durables and raise the share of consumption in GDP. And, as interna-tional experience shows, a growing middle class will also act as a catalyst for improved governance, better delivery of public services, and the empowerment of civil society. And finally, C hina’s urbanization—a driver of much of China’s increased global competitiveness—is poised to grow rapidly. Over the coming two decades, the increase in the urban population will be the equiva-lent of more than one Tokyo or Buenos Aires each year as the share of urban residents in the total population climbs from about one-half to near two-thirds in 2030.10 This will act as another powerful driver of growth,

although much will depend on how well

TABLe 1 China: Projected growth pattern assuming steady reforms and no major shock

GDP growth (percent per year)

9.9 8.6 7.0 5.9 5.0 Labor growth

0.9 0.3 –0.2 –0.2 –0.4 Labor productivity growth

8.9 8.3 7.1 6.2 5.5

Structure of economy (end of period, %)

Investment/GDP ratio

46.4 42 38 36 34 Consumption/GDP ratio

48.6 56 60 63 66

Industry/GDP ratio

46.9 43.8 41.0 38.0 34.6 Services/GDP ratio

43.0 47.6 51.6 56.1 61.1

Share of employment in agriculture

38.1 30.0 23.7 18.2 12.5 Share of employment in services

34.1 42.0 47.6 52.9 59.0

Source: DRC.

10 c h i n a2030

urban development policies are designed and implemented.

Opportunities and risks

going forward

These global and internal trends offer China many opportunities that could support rapid growth in the next two decades—and give rise to many risks that could threaten that growth. Any development strategy going for-ward would need to build on the opportuni-ties and manage the risks.

First consider the opportunities. C on-tinued rapid economic development and decreases in inequality will swell the ranks of the middle class and accelerate domestic demand for income-elastic products, such as consumer durables, leisure activities, and housing, as well as better health and educa-tion services. This, together with the rapid growth of other emerging markets where similar transformations are taking place (albeit at a slower pace) will afford new opportunities to Chinese enterprises, enable economies of scale in production and market-ing, and provide fresh incentives to increase international competitiveness through inno-vation and technological development.

Increased specialization, intraindustry trade, and the two-way flow of investment will allow C hina to continue to exploit opportunities to narrow the gap between its capabilities and the technological frontier through adoption, adaptation, and mastery of existing technologies. The country’s high savings rates will allow it to replenish its capi-tal stock relatively quickly, and that will con-tinue to facilitate rapid technological catch-up (figure 2). And with improvements in its own research and development capabilities, China itself could become a global source of product and process innovation as well as occasional technological breakthroughs.

China’s growing technological prowess will lead to rapid change in its industrial struc-ture, which will create new areas of dynamic comparative advantage. Just as its construc-tion industry has become a global leader in construction projects internationally, so too will other industries become a competitive force in global markets in their own right. This transition would present an opportunity to improve quality, safety, and environmental standards that would provide a competitive edge abroad and improve consumer experi-ence at home.

Growing recognition within C hina that the current pattern of production and growth is unsustainable is giving rise to new approaches toward realigning government priorities. A fresh emphasis on the qual-ity—not just the pace—of growth provides a promising opportunity to encourage compe-tition between local governments on the basis of a broad development index incorporating a mix of social and environmental measures that can be added to existing indicators of economic growth. Realignment of priorities would also be consistent with the expected increase in demand from the rising number of middle-class Chinese seeking improvements in their quality of life.

At the same time, global and domestic trends are also likely to give rise to many risks that could slow economic growth and disrupt China’s progress to become a high-income, harmonious, and creative society. Managing the transition from a middle-income to a high-income society will itself prove challenging, and a global environment that will likely remain uncertain and vola-tile for the foreseeable future makes the task doubly daunting. The next five years will be particularly risky as the global economy enters a new and dangerous phase and works its way through the aftereffects of the global financial crisis and adjusts to the “new normal.”

There is broad consensus that C hina’s growth is likely to slow, but when and at what pace is uncertain, and there is no say-ing whether this slowdown will be smooth or not. Any sudden slowdown could unmask inefficiencies and contingent liabilities in banks, enterprises, and different levels of government—heretofore hidden under the veil of rapid growth—and could precipitate a fiscal and financial crisis. The implications for social stability would be hard to predict in such a scenario.

o v e r v i e w 11How government responds to a rapid

slowdown will depend on its causes. One

cause could be a macroeconomic shock, say,

a sudden decline in real estate prices and a

sharp contraction in construction and invest-

ment, or a rapid growth slowdown in the

advanced economies leading to sharply lower

global trade and growth. Such risks could be

significant in the short term, and there is a

likelihood that China could face just such

challenges over the course of the next two

decades. Fortunately, unlike many other

countries, China’s fiscal and debt position

allows it the space to respond with counter-

cyclical measures. But these short-term policy

responses should also be supportive of long-

term structural reforms (such as those recom-

mended in this report).

Another cause of a growth slowdown—

arguably one of greater concern—could be

structural in nature, the so-called middle-

income trap (box 1). If, instead of respond-

ing with policy reforms to address structural

problems, the government applies macroeco-

nomic measures to stimulate the economy,

then inflation and instability could result,

possibly undermining investor confidence

and ultimately leading to slower growth and

even stagnation. Over the past half century, many countries have entered middle-income status, but very few have made the additional leap to become high-income economies. Rather, several faced sudden, sharp decel-erations in growth and have been unsuccess-ful in addressing the root structural cause of the slowdown. China does not have to endure this fate. Successful implementa-tion of the reform policies, contained in this report, aimed at finding new growth driv-ers—increased efficiency in input use, higher human capital investments, increased innova-tion, and a shift to high-value services—will help China avoid the middle-income trap and maintain an expected average growth rate of between 6 and 7 percent a year in the com-ing two decades, compared with an average of nearly 10 percent a year in the past three decades. The risk of sharply lower growth rates is exacerbated by China’s relatively high income and asset inequality, low consumption, and unequal access to quality public services (fig-ure 3). Notwithstanding massive internal migration from farms to cities, barriers to labor mobility (the household registration, or hukou , system, the lack of portability of pen-sion plans, weak labor market institutions, and inadequate job market information) have

FIgUre 2 Savings in China compared to other countries

Source: World Bank 2011b.010

2030405060

–10–5years since reforms

a. High savings will continue to be key to

China’s rapid growth . . .

b. . . . which was high even by East Asia’s high standards China (year 0 = 1978)

Former Soviet Union (year 0 = 1990)

Eastern and Central Europe (developing) (year 0 = 1990)0+5+10+15+20+25+30g r o s s d o m e s t i c e a r n i n g s (% o f G D P )g r o s s d o m e s t i c e a r n i n g s (% o f G D P )0010,00020,00030,00040,00050,000

102030405060 GDP per capita, constant prices China (1974–2009)Malaysia (1965–2009)

Korea, Rep. (1965–2009)

Singapore (1965–2009)Thailand (1965–2009)Hong Kong SAR, China (1965–2009)

Japan (1974–2009)

12 c h i n a2030

trapped tens of millions of farm families in low-paying, low-productivity work. These barriers, combined with factor and resource price policies that favor enterprise profits and implicitly tax household incomes, have con-tributed to the declining share of wages and rising share of capital in national income. Furthermore, the quality gap in public ser-vices available to rural and urban households has widened, and the “opportunity gap” between urban and rural areas has grown. Social tensions have ratcheted up in some

Source: Heston, Summers, and Aten 2011. Source: Maddison database.

a. T he term “middle-income trap” was first defined in Gill, Kharas, and others (2007). “Middle income economies” are defined in accordance with classifications by

income group as given in: https://www.360docs.net/doc/166744857.html,/about/country-classifications.

b. I n today’s increasingly globalized world, escaping the middle-income trap may be even more difficult (Eeckhout and Jovanovic 2007).

o v e r v i e w

13

areas, resulting in a growing number of pub-lic protests. Unresolved, these tensions could pose a threat to growth and stability in com-ing decades.

Social risks are also expected to arise from another direction. If the experiences of other countries is any guide, the rising ranks of the middle class and higher education levels will inevitably increase the demand for bet-ter social governance and greater opportuni-ties for participation in public policy debate and implementation. Unmet, these demands could raise social tensions; but if the gov-ernment finds ways to improve consultation and tap the knowledge and social capital of individuals and nongovernment agencies, these demands can be transformed into a positive force supportive of improved gover-nance and public policy formulation.

Another risk relates to C hina’s growth pattern, which has been particularly intensive in energy and natural resource use, contribut-ing to a widening environmental deficit and exposing the economy to commodity price shocks. While the rise in energy intensity in individual industries has eased steadily, rapid growth, growing urbanization, and struc-tural change within manufacturing have combined to make China the world’s largest energy user, outstripping the United States

FIgUre 3 China’s economic challenges

Source: Milanovic 2005; World Bank calculations.Source: World Bank 2010.

14 c h i n a2030

in 2010 (although, on a per capita basis, the United States still consumes five times more energy than C hina, and C hina has raced ahead in generating wind and solar energy). Similarly, rapid growth has led to substan-tial natural resource depletion and serious environmental pollution. Uncorrected, these trends could, in time, serve as a serious con-straint on growth.

Many of the policies that generated Chi-na’s high savings and investment levels also account for its external imbalance, as mea-sured by its current and capital account sur-pluses in the balance of payments. The com-bination of these two surpluses has resulted in record foreign exchange reserves, most of which are invested in low-yield U.S. securi-ties, while China pays a substantially higher interest or dividend rate for capital imports in the form of “hot money” and foreign direct investment. China’s current account surpluses and reserve accumulation are a relatively recent phenomenon, one that occurred only after the Asian financial crisis. They reflect not only the country’s growing role as the center of a rapidly expanding and deepening East Asian production network but also a policy objective to strengthen the country’s foreign exchange buffer against external shocks. Ironically, these reserves face the risk of large capital losses in the face of a weakened dollar. Efforts to export capital in the form of outward FDI, especially to secure raw material supplies, has met with suspi-cion in some receiving countries, and unless appropriate steps are taken to address these problems, such risks and friction could grow.

China’s relations with the rest of the world are affected by its rapid export growth, which has not been matched with equivalent increases in import volumes, and by bilateral trade surpluses with its key trading partners, which have fueled protectionist pressures. Indeed, if China’s current export growth per-sists, its projected global market share could rise to 20 percent by 2030, almost double the peak of Japan’s global market share in the mid-1980s when it faced fierce protectionist sentiments from its trading partners. China’s current trajectory, if continued, would cause unmanageable trade frictions well before 2030, however. The anemic growth of high-income countries as they continue to struggle with fiscal consolidation is expected only to magnify China’s expansion of the global market share.

o v e r v i e w15

China’ successful development strategy over the past three decades has made it an upper-middle-income economy today. But the opportunities and challenges in the next two decades will be unlike those it encountered in the past and will demand a new development strategy. This strategy will need to build on China’s opportunities, meet its challenges, manage its risks, and realize the country’s long-term objectives. But what are those objectives—and what kind of strategy does China need to achieve them? This chapter begins with a discussion of China’s vision of itself in 2030, identifies the core elements of a strategy that would help it realize that vision, and examines the characteristics that such a strategy should have.

The 2030 vision: To build a modern, harmonious, and creative high-income society

In a recent landmark study, the Commission on Growth and Development (2008) identi-fied five common features in countries that sustained rapid growth and development for extended periods: They exploited opportu-nities in the world economy by maintain-ing open trade and investment policies; they maintained macroeconomic stability; they enjoyed high savings and investment rates; they allowed markets to allocate resources; and they were led by committed and cred-ible governments. C hina belongs to this select group and has demonstrated all five of these features. The architect of China’s reforms was Deng Xiaoping, who played an important role in building consensus for a fundamental shift in the country’s strategy. After more than 30 years of rapid growth, China has reached another turning point in its development path, one that calls for a second strategic, and no less fundamental, shift.

China’s ultimate objective is to become a modern, harmonious, creative, and high-income society by 2030. Each element of the phrase “modern, harmonious, creative, and high income” has specific significance in China that guides the analysis and recom-mendations in this report.

A modern society is industrialized and urbanized and enjoys a quality of life that is on par with the Western world. This society would have modern values, a modern eco-nomic and social structure, with access to contemporary, state-of-the-art product and process technologies, and would engage and contribute as an equal with other nations in the discourse of the modern world on all subjects.

As a harmonious society,China sees three interrelated goals. First, its own policies need to be inclusive and just, aimed at eliminating most social and economic boundaries and at building a society in which everyone has a common stake in the country’s economic, social, legal, and political institutions. China would like to see a society where people show mutual respect, disputes are resolved justly and peacefully through accepted norms, laws, regulations, and practices—and the institutional structure is quick to adapt to society’s changing needs and aspirations. Second, China sees itself living in balance with nature, in which its ecological foot-print—the use of resources and creation of waste—are consistent with the biological capacity of its (and the world’s) land, water, and air resources given existing technology. And third, China would like to see itself as an equal, constructive, and accepted partner in the community of nations, working peace-fully and cooperatively toward common goals, and engaging constructively on global issues and in global institutions.

As a creative society, C hina sees itself building its future prosperity on innovation in which everyone’s creative potential is tapped. Its success will lie in its ability to produce more value, not more products, enabling it to move up the value chain and compete glob-ally in the same product space as advanced countries. Creativity will manifest itself not just in product and process technology, but also in cultural and artistic pursuits. If suc-cessful, China’s experience could potentially be a beacon for other middle-income devel-oping countries to follow.

Chapter 2 A New Development Strategy for 2030

16 c h i n a2030

As a high-income society, China’s aspira-tion is to enjoy a per capita income on par with advanced economies; have a large mid-dle class that acts as a force for stability, good governance, and economic progress; elimi-nate poverty as it is known today; and pro-mote social harmony by increasing equality of opportunity and lowering inequality in all its economic and social dimensions.

If C hina achieves its goal of becoming a high-income society by 2030, it will be the world’s largest economy using market prices (indeed, if GDP is measured by pur-chasing power parity, it could well outstrip the United States later this decade). China’s incremental size in the coming two decades will be equivalent to 15 of today’s Korea’s. Even so, its annual per capita income will still be around $16,000, more than three times today’s level, close to today’s Slovakia or Korea, and slightly more than a third of today’s United States.

Another reality in 2030 that can be fore-told with some accuracy will be C hina’s demographic transition. Simply put, China will grow old before it grows rich. Its low fertility rate and consequent low population growth rate will mean a rising share of old people in the economy. The old-age depen-dency ratio—defined as the ratio of those aged 65 and over to those between the ages of 15 and 64—will double over the next

20 years (UN 2010; UN 2009). By 2030,

C hina’s dependency ratio will reach the level of Norway and the Netherlands today. Just as important, C hina’s working-age population will decline after 2015. The urban share of the population is expected to rise from around 50 percent today to near two-thirds by 2030, an average growth of 13 million people each year (NBSC 2011; UN 2010).

Compared with today, China’s economy in 2030 will be more complex, market driven, knowledge centered, and oriented toward services. Its trade and financial integration with the global economy will make it more interdependent with other economies and at the same time more vulnerable to external shocks. It will have deeper and more stable financial markets, which can lay the founda-tion for an open capital account and broad acceptance of the renminbi as an interna-tional reserve currency. The government’s economic priority will shift to maintaining macroeconomic stability, creating an invest-ment and regulatory environment conducive for enterprise development, and financing public goods and services. C hina will be competing internationally in the same prod-uct space as the advanced economies; its uni-versity graduates will have tripled in num-ber; and its environment will be significantly cleaner. Moreover, with a larger urban popu-lation and more efficient transportation and movement of labor between cities and the countryside, inequality between urban and rural areas will continue to decline.

The case for a new strategy Realizing C hina’s vision for 2030 will demand a new development strategy. The development strategy it pursued over the past three decades was directed at meet-ing the challenges of a different era. Not only have the challenges changed, so have China’s capabilities. No strategy lasts for-ever. Successful strategies must be flexible and adjust in accordance with changing con-ditions. Middle-income countries unable to make such adjustments have stumbled into the middle-income trap. China’s top deci-sion makers recognize this and have made transforming the economic development pat-tern the country’s most important economic policy priority.

Changing the development model is urgent because, as an economy approaches the tech-nology frontier and exhausts the potential for acquiring and applying technology from abroad, the role of the government needs to change fundamentally. Initiating this change early helps smooth the transition from importing new technologies to innovating and creating new technologies.

Developing countries tend to benefit from the latecomer’s advantage by following a development path adopted by others. This path makes the role of government relatively straightforward—providing roads, railways, energy, and other infrastructure to comple-ment private investment, allowing open trade and investment policies that encourage

o v e r v i e w17

technological catch-up, and implementing industrial policies when market and coor-dination failures inhibit the development of internationally competitive industries consis-tent with the country’s comparative advan-tage. The development strategies of East Asia’s successful economies—Japan; Korea; Hong Kong SAR, C hina; Singapore; and Taiwan, China—have all broadly reflected these features.

But when a developing country reaches the technology frontier, the correct devel-opment strategy ceases to be so straightfor-ward. Direct government intervention may actually retard growth, not help it. Instead, the policy emphasis needs to shift even more toward private sector development, ensuring that markets are mature enough to allocate resources efficiently and that firms are strong and innovative enough to compete interna-tionally in technologically advanced sectors.

The role of the private sector is critical because innovation at the technology frontier is quite different in nature from simply catch-ing up technologically. The process becomes essentially one of trial and error, with the chances of success highly uncertain. Innova-tion is not something that can be achieved through government planning. Indeed, the more enterprises are involved in the trial-and-error process of innovation, the greater are the chances for technological breakthroughs, and the more likely that new discoveries will be translated into commercially viable prod-ucts. As enterprises take a leading role, the government needs to adopt a more supportive and facilitating role.

One of the key supportive roles the gov-ernment can play is enhancing the quality of human capital. China’s rapid growth has been accompanied by a gradual decline in its agricultural surplus labor and a steady rise in real wages in manufacturing, a trend that appears to have accelerated recently. Without concomitant increases in labor pro-ductivity, real wage increases could lead to a steady decline in international competitive-ness. Increasing the quality of human capital will not only increase labor productivity and maintain China’s competitiveness; it will also allow Chinese manufacturing and services to move up the value chain. Improvement in the quality of human capital will require bet-ter education, health care, and social secu-rity. And it will demand a marked increase in equal employment opportunities and self-employment, as well as greater lateral mobility of labor from rural to urban areas and across towns, cities, provinces, and occu-pations, and vertical mobility through the social, economic, and political hierarchies.

Another supportive role the govern-ment can play is encouraging greater par-ticipation in the development process. The expanding middle class is increasingly vocal in its demand to participate in the discus-sion of public policy. This demand points to a broader need to empower people to con-tribute to the country’s development efforts, be creative, and improve standards of living through their own efforts. The government should respond proactively to these needs and grant rights to individuals, households, enter-prises, communities, academia, and other nongovernmental organizations through clear rules that encourage broad participa-tion. By doing so, the government can gradu-ally transfer some of its previous functions to society at large, allow nongovernmental players to form networks in new and inter-esting ways, and create space for innovation and creativity. Moreover, empowering soci-ety, especially those who are disadvantaged, will help unleash new ideas and approaches toward increasing equality of opportunity, ensuring inclusive growth, and achieving a balance between a caring and a competitive society.

Last, while the government reduces its role in markets, resource allocation, production, and distribution, it should step up its role in financing public goods and services, protect-ing the environment, increasing equality of opportunity, and ensuring an environment conducive for private sector development. Playing such an indirect and supportive role is complicated but will have a wide impact, with greater leverage through the private sector and social organizations. While pro-viding fewer “tangible” goods and services directly, the government will need to provide more intangible public goods and services, like systems, rules, and policies, that increase production efficiency, promote competition,

18 c h i n a2030

facilitate specialization, enhance the effi-ciency of resource allocation, and reduce risks and uncertainties. It requires designing and implementing incentive structures that lead to desired and sustainable outcomes.

One key area, for example, is the financ-ing of basic public services such as pensions, medical care, education, and housing, where the government can invest more, drawing on resources it had previously devoted to infrastructure and manufacturing. Equally important, the government should be less concerned with whether the private or the public sector provides these public goods and services—but instead focus on ensuring they are delivered efficiently and to the requisite quality. Encouraging the private provision of public goods and services and forming public-private partnerships where appropri-ate will not only inject new skills and ideas into public service delivery but also empower the private sector and encourage greater participation in the development process. Another example is the environment, an area requiring strong action by the government. Not only will green development improve the quality of life in China, it will contribute to global efforts at mitigating climate change. As the second-largest economy with the larg-est population in the world, China is bound to shoulder increasing global responsibili-ties and play an important role in delivering global public goods. To do this, it will need to align its national interests to global con-cerns and build its capacity to participate actively in global affairs and to design global rules instead of merely accepting them.

In sum, it is imperative that China adjusts its development strategy as it embarks on its next phase of economic growth. At its core, this adjustment requires changing the role of government and its relations with the mar-ket, the private sector, and society at large. While the government needs to withdraw from direct involvement in production, dis-tribution, and resource allocation, it will need to focus greater attention on design-ing and implementing the policy and regu-latory framework that empowers others to participate in economic decision making so that the desired outcome of rapid, inclusive, and sustainable growth is achieved. To play this role, the government will need to trans-form itself into a lean, clean, transparent, and highly efficient modern government that operates under the rule of law. In redefining its role, the government will need to accel-erate reforms in the state-owned sector and combine it with further development of the private sector. It will also need to advance reforms in factor markets (capital, land, and labor) to help strengthen the foundations of a market economy and promote greater competition and innovation. At the same time, society’s role will need to change sig-nificantly, with the middle class becoming a major force in promoting harmonious devel-opment through greater participation of the people in the development process.

Key characteristics of the

new strategy

Before describing a proposed development strategy, it is worth highlighting five charac-teristics that should lie at its core.

The first is improvement in the qual-ity of growth while continuing to increase incomes. Not only does C hina aspire to become a high-income society that enjoys sustained growth, it would like to see growth measured in qualitative as well as quantita-tive terms. Rising incomes need to be accom-panied by increased leisure, a better physical environment, expanding arts and cultural activities, and a greater sense of economic and social security. C orrespondingly, the incentive structure that drives central and local government performance will also need to reflect this changed emphasis. China needs to develop a new metric to measure prog-ress over the coming decades that balances growth and income objectives with broader welfare and sustainability goals.

The second is to achieve balanced and sustainable growth, consistent with mar-ket forces.There is broad recognition in C hina—as reflected in the 11th and 12th Five Year Plans—that the country’s pattern of investment and growth has become largely unsustainable. Spurred by high savings, cheap finance, and export-oriented policies, C hina’s impressive growth rate has been capital intensive, industry led, and export

o v e r v i e w19

dependent for several years. Compared with rapidly growing manufacturing, the develop-ment of services has lagged (though the sta-tistics may exaggerate the degree of lag). The shares of wages and consumption in national income have fallen steadily; the shares of capital and investment have climbed. Rural-urban inequality has expanded since the 1990s. China is home to more than a million millionaires,11 while more than 170 million live on less than $2 a day.12

Returning to balanced and sustainable growth will require a rise in the shares spent on services and consumption as per capita income increases. This will be achieved, in part, by correcting factor price distortions that implicitly tax labor and subsidize capi-tal. Correcting such distortions and allowing market-driven structural change will not only help achieve greater balance between manu-facturing and services but also in the distri-bution of income between capital and labor and between rural and urban households.

The third is to strengthen innovation and creativity. While development of services will need to be a priority in the coming decades, manufacturing growth will continue to be an important growth driver. After all, notwith-standing recent rapid increases in real wages, China’s low-cost labor, especially in inte-rior, less-developed provinces, will remain an advantage for many years to come. But rather than focus purely on growth, poli-cies will need to encourage manufacturers to move up the value chain and advance rap-idly to the global technology frontier (and, in some areas, push that technology frontier forward). Services like research and devel-opment (R&D), finance, logistics, training, information services, and after-sale services will help. Achieving this will require further integration with the global economy and increased specialization, as well as participa-tion in global R&D networks and marketing arrangements.

But it would be a mistake to believe that innovation will be restricted to manufac-turing. If China is successful in nurturing a culture of open innovation, then the services sector could also be an important beneficiary, and there is no reason why China should not become an important exporter of high-end services. Most services have become trad-able internationally, and China can benefit from agglomeration economies and interna-tional specialization in services just as it has in manufacturing. For example, if China suc-ceeds in becoming a leading innovator in the field of green development, then its expertise and knowledge on this subject will likely be sought worldwide. Similarly, if China’s finan-cial sector is strengthened to the point that the capital account can be liberalized and the renminbi become a key international reserve currency, then China could become a key exporter of financial services.

The fourth is unleashing China’s full human potential.Equality of opportu-nity will not only help unleash China’s full human potential, it will also support inclu-sive growth and improve income distribution. Increasing equality of opportunity should not be restricted only to public services, such as health or education; it should also include economic opportunities such as access to jobs, finance, or official permits to start a business. One way to increase equality of opportunity in the enterprise and financial sectors will be to allow more competition in factor markets (labor, land, and capital) as well as product markets. More competition, of course, can come from abroad through boosting exports and lowering import barri-ers, but it can also be encouraged by easing the entry and exit of firms in the domestic market, giving small and medium enterprises (SMEs) greater access to finance and market opportunities, opening up public procure-ment by making procedures transparent, and creating new opportunities for the private provision of public services by separating financing from delivery. Smarter and more effective regulation can do more than just help level the playing field between big enter-prises and small ones. It can also help protect consumers, workers, and the environment; safeguard private and intellectual property rights; ensure greater financial sector stabil-ity; and provide a solid foundation for corpo-rate governance to guide enterprises.

Equality of opportunity also means higher public participation in public policy formu-lation, implementation, and oversight. As economies grow in size and complexity, the

20 c h i n a2030

task of economic management becomes more complicated, and governments usually find that they alone do not, indeed should not, have all the answers. Governments, there-fore, tend to tap the knowledge and social capital of individuals and nongovernment agencies, including universities, communities, and think tanks. One of the hallmarks of advanced economies is their public discussion of public policies. Indeed, such discussions are already beginning in China, but there is a long way to go. Public consultations and policy debate ensure that all points of view are considered before government reforms are introduced. These discussions not only shrink the distance between the government and the citizens and communities it serves, but they also encourages stakeholders’ own-ership of new policies, help render reform proposals intelligible to citizens and firms, and enhance the chances of success.

The fifth (and last) values the role of the market, rule of law, social values, and high moral standards.As the government tran-sitions away from direct intervention in enterprise and market activities and toward creating a policy and regulatory environ-ment supportive of free and fair competition, it must also safeguard the rule of law. In a similar vein, as the Chinese economy grows in complexity, not only must rules and regu-lations evolve to reflect changing reality and emerging priorities, but they should be fairly and effectively enforced. If the enforcement of standards varies from sector to sector, region to region, entity to entity, and some-times even person to person, then it will not only discourage innovation and lead to ineffi-cient economic outcomes, it will also contrib-ute to feelings of injustice. Where contract disputes arise, whether between private par-ties or between private entities and the State, the disputants should have access not only to legal recourse but also to a transparent and effective judicial system that imparts justice without fear or favor.

Similarly, social values and high moral standards will be important. There is wide-spread concern in China over many recent instances of “moral failures” that were reported widely in the media. As C hina becomes a high-income society, its social values and moral standards should be reex-amined and reinforced. From a social per-spective, not only will this contribute to improving the quality of life, it will also provide a greater sense of community and enhance social cohesion. From an economic perspective, it will reduce transaction costs and improve the quality of economic gov-ernance. Promoting social values and high moral standards is not only the job of gov-ernment; it is also the duty of social orga-nizations and, indeed, every citizen. Moral awareness, not legal compulsion, should be the hallmark of a high-income, harmonious society.

Six key directions of the

new strategy

Over the next two decades, China will face many challenges in its quest to become a modern, harmonious, and creative high-income society. These include transitioning government from being an active partici-pant in the economy to developing the legal, regulatory, and institutional framework sup-portive of a competitive market environment; implementing a “smart” urbanization strat-egy; encouraging innovation and industrial upgrading; reducing income inequality and ensuring equal opportunity for all; modify-ing its approach toward handling economic relations with other countries; and playing a more constructive role in a rapidly chang-ing system of global governance. In reality, the list of challenges is much longer. While some consensus has emerged with respect to a few of those issues, controversies remain and an intense debate is ongoing over key aspects. This report evaluates the major chal-lenges China needs to tackle in the next two decades and identifies six new strategic direc-tions that will form the core components of the new strategy.

The first new strategic direction is the role of the state and the private sector. The recent global financial crisis in the advanced economies and, in stark contrast, C hina’s continued rapid growth despite the global slowdown, have led some in China to conclude that China’s state domi-nance in key industrial and service sectors

中国经济发展的历程与现状与发展趋势.

中国经济发展的历程与现状及发展趋势 社会经济的现代化贯通于资本主义产生、发展和社会主义确立、发展的全过程,是人类社会从传统的农业文明向现代工业文明转变的必然趋势。从内容上看,它是以科技为动力,以工业化为中心,以机器生产为标志,并引起经济结构、政治制度、生活方式、思想观念全方位变化的一场社会变革。 一、鸦片战争后中国社会经济结构的变动 1、自然经济开始解体 1842年五口通商以后,西方商品输人与日俱增,尤其是洋纱洋布的输入,摧毁了东南沿海地区中国传统的家庭手工棉纺织业,造成纺与织、织与耕的分离。传统的小农业与家庭手工业相结合的自给自足的自然经济开始解体。其后,随着更多的通商口岸的开放,洋纱洋布得以倾销,进而为机器棉纱纺织业的产生和发展准备了一定的原料和产品市场;陷入破产与失业的农民和手工业者,则为近代机器工业提供了劳动力市场。 传统的自给自足的自然经济开始瓦解只是发生在沿海局部地区,内地广阔的农村封建生产关系基本没变。另外,在东南沿海地区,棉纺等中国传统的手工业部门也同时受到打击和排挤,这些部门的资本主义萌芽受到遏制。 2、近代机器工业的出现 19世纪40年代外国资本的近代机器工业在中国出现。60年代开始的洋务运动,标志着中国工业近代化的开始。 鸦片战争后,外国商人为了贸易和航运的需要,在通商口岸私自创办了一批船舶维修厂、砖茶厂和机器缫丝厂等。外国企业在中国的开办,给中国带来了先进的机器与技术,打开了中国人的眼界,从而为中国资本主义机器工业的产生起了诱导的作用。

自19世纪60年代始,李鸿章、左宗棠等洋务派大官僚,先后创办了江南制造总局、金陵机器局、福州船政局、天津机器局等军事工业,清政府各省当局大多也创办了自己的军火生产机构。这些军事工业从外国购进设备生产船舰、枪炮、弹药,将大机器工业引入了中国。洋务派在这一时期所创办的上海机器织布局、汉阳铁厂等民用工业,也都属于使用机器生产的近代企业。除制造业外,洋务派大官僚李鸿章等人创办了上海轮船招商局、开平矿务局、天津电报总局,修筑了铁路,从而建立了中国自己的近代采矿、航运、铁路和通讯事业。 二、中国社会经济近代化进程的阶段 1.初步发展阶段(1840~1895 年) (1)鸦片战争后,西方列强利用不平等条约的特权向中国倾销商品,并非法开办企业(这是在中国最早出现使用机器生产的近代工业)。 (2)洋务运动,兴办了一批近代军事和民用工业。洋务运动是中国早期现代化的第一次大规模实践,产生了中国机器工业。 (3)19 世纪六、七十年代,中国民族资本主义工业兴起。民族资本主义工业冲击自然经济,中国社会的经济结构发生了重要的变化。 2.整体发展阶段:(1895—1927 年) (1)甲午战争后民族资本主义经济初步发展。 (2)1912—1919 年民族资本主义经济进一步发展。 3.曲折前进阶段(1927—1949 年) (1)国民政府统治前期,官僚资本形成,民族工业发展。 (2)抗战期间,原有的工业在军国主义的大举进攻下遭到严重摧残,近代化被打断。

(2015版)第八章建设中国特色社会主义总布局习题

第八章建设中国特色社会主义总布局 第一节建设中国特色社会主义经济 一、填空 1.社会主义经济建设、政治建设、文化建设、社会建设和生态文明建设五位一体,是建设中国特色社会主义的总布局。 2. 改革开放开始后一个很长时期内,我国经济体制改革的核心问题是如何正确认识和处理计划与市场的关系。 3. 社会主义市场经济的基本特征主要体现在所有制结构、分配制度、宏观调控三个方面。 4. 公有制为主体、多种所有制经济共同发展,是我国社会主义初级阶段的基本经济制度。 5.从要素驱动、投资驱动转向创新驱动是经济发展新常态的特点之一。 二、选择单选 1. 我们党在经济体制改革中的一个伟大创举是提出(A) A.把社会主义和市场经济结合起来 B.股份制是公有制实现形式 C.把公有制与非公经济相结合 D.把按劳分配与按生产要素分配相结合 2. 社会主义市场经济体制的基础是(C) A.以间接手段为主的完善的宏观调控体系 B.统一、开放、竞争、有序的市场体系 C.以公有制为主体的现代企业制度 D.合理的个人收入分配和社会保障制度 3. 社会主义初级阶段与新民主主义社会的本质区别,从所有制结构看,在于:(D) A.存在多种所有制经济 B.非公有制经济是社会主义经济的必要的补充 C.国有经济起主导作用 D.公有制经济主体地位的确立 4. 社会主义经济制度与以往一切私有制为基础的社会经济制度的根本区别在于消灭剥削和消除两极分化,实现这一点的制度性保障条件是(A) A.必须坚持公有制和按劳分配 B.必须坚持效率优先,兼顾公平的原则 C.必须实行按生产要素分配D.必须加大收入分配调节力度 5. 社会主义市场经济体制的基础是(A) A.以公有制为主体的现代企业制度 B.计划与市场相结合的调节机制 C.统一、开放、竞争、有序的市场体系 D.完善的宏观经济调控体系 6. 国有经济在国民经济中的主导作用主要表现在(C) A.国有资产在社会总资产申占有量的优势 B.国有经济能控制垄断性行业 C.国有经济对国民经济的控制力 D.国有经济在国民经济中占主体地位 7. 某员工在外资企业工作,年薪5万元;利用业余时间在民营企业兼职,年薪2万元;购

浅谈当代中国经济发展形势

浅谈当代中国经济发展形势 崔宝林 改革开放30多年来,国家经济实力大幅增强,人民生活水平显著提高,为全面建设小康社会奠定了坚实的基础。在迎来改革开放的第三十三个年头之际,作为当代大学生的我们,对国家的经济发展也抱有足够的信心和满心的期待。 下面浅谈对当前中国经济发展的形势的个人见解。 我们国家在过去几十年经济的快速增长时期,主要是依靠投资带动。而这种集中于基础设施、机器设备和厂房等方面的资本投入,不仅获得了相应的回报,同时也得到了市场认可。在参与全球贸易分工过程中,随着产业的专业化、规模化发展,劳动力和劳动技能的持续提高,也是中国经济增长的重要因素之一。 中国经济发展呈现的是资本投入与GDP产出同步增加的现状,而没有出现资本投资的边际收益递减的效应。因此我们不需过于担心世界经济放缓和外贸出口的下降会对中国GDP增长产生太大影响。 虽然我国已成为全球第二大经济体,GDP总量约6万亿美元,美国约为15万亿,但人均水平仅相当于美国的十一分之一。主要因为我们的经济社会发展在延续“黄金发展期”态势的同时,也面临诸多矛盾的凸显、各种挑战日趋严峻的态势,社会、经济的整体转轨正在经受历史性的考验的缘故。 尽管如此,中国经济的增长势头并没有改变。目前正处于调整和改革期,虽然增速出现一定幅度回落,但也只是经济增速的短期回落,并不意味着中国经济进入了新的衰退阶段。而且目前中国经济发展已

经表现出积极向好的变化: 首先,挤出了“泡沫”,缓解了通胀压力。制造业购进价格指数显示,上游产品价格涨势明显减缓。从目前来看,一些行业产品价格回落到较低水平,影响了企业的正常效益,对此企业要引起自身发展的关注点,不可以盲目扩张的方式获取利益。 其次,结构向优化改善方向发展。从PMI来看,当前第三产业发展好于第二产业。今年以来,服务业商务活动指数保持在较高水平,与去年同期相差不大,发展较为稳健。在第二产业当中,制造业发展势头好于采掘业。而在制造业领域,装备制造业又好于基础原材料加工业。1-5月份,电气机械及器材制造业PMI平均为55.7%,明显高于钢铁、有色、化工等行业,这些行业PMI平均为48.9%-52%之间。这些方面反映出,经济结构和产业结构都在不断优化,不断改善。 第三,就业保持稳定增长。制造业从业人员指数,自3月份以来,一直保持在50%以上,5月份为50.5%;非制造业从业人员指数自年初以来稳定地保持在50%以上。两组数据均显示出就业保持稳定增长,有利于提高公民收入、扩大国内消费需求,使经济发展保持稳定增长动力。 中国转变经济发展方式过程中,由于经济增速回落、结构调整,也不可避免地会出现一些新的问题和矛盾。当前面临的突出问题是经济增长基础尚需巩固。另一个方面是小企业发展困难增加。小企业受政策利好带动,年初曾出现短暂回升,最近三月持续回落,反映小企业在经济增速回落过程中,受到的影响更为显著。

我国经济发展现状的论文

我国经济发展现状的论文 导读 《中国分享经济发展报告2021》对分享经济下的概念是:利用互联网等现代技术整合,分享海量的分散化闲置资源,满足多样化需求的经济活动总和。从对共享经济的定义和概述中可提炼出三点:一是可利用的闲置资源;二是共享平台高效供需对接;三是资源供需双方的积极参与。 共享经济概述 (一)共享经济的成因和内涵 共享经济是一种新兴经济形态。1987年,美国学者马科斯·费尔逊、琼·斯潘思提出分享消费是在满足日常需求的同时愿意与他人建立关系的经济活动。雷切尔·波茨曼、鲁斯·罗杰斯在《我的就是你的:协作消费的崛起》一书中,进一步发展了分享消费的观点,指出客户的需求不再局限于拥有物品的所有权而是使用需求获得满足。罗宾·蔡斯在《共享经济:重构未来商业新模式》一书中,把共享经济的含义归为三部分:产能过剩(闲置资源)、共享平台、人人参与。共享经济鼓励物品的所有权者与目标使用者基于共享平台,提高闲置资源的使用效率,提倡人与人之间以互信的方式交流、生活。

从对共享经济的定义和概述中可提炼出三点:一是可利用的闲置资源;二是共享平台高效供需对接;三是资源供需双方的积极参与。 共享经济包含共享平台、供给方、需求方三个必须主体。 1.共享平台 基于互联网等现代技术,把可利用的闲置资源位置应用大数据基本算法等精准实时对接供给端与需求端,平台本身对共享的物品与服务没有所有权,未对其进行相应的固定成本支出,提供的仅仅是必须的服务与法定的监管,属于轻资产运营,收入来自交易的抽成。 2.供给方 供给方无论是个体或是组织,只要拥有闲置可用的资源,并且愿意为获取一定收益而暂时性转移产品使用权或服务,供给方的本质是在获取额外收益的同时而不自觉地提高了资源的使用效率。 3.需求方 需求方是愿意付出一定的经济报酬而获取物品的使用权或接受服务。在互联网经济下,每个有需求的个体或组织均可成为产品或服务的需求方,无须拥有产品所有权而获取产品和服务需求。 在互联网经济下,共享经济完美地实现了供给与需求的无缝对接,供给因能提供“私人订制”的解决方案而提高了产品与服

当前中国经济发展的优劣势分析

当前中国经济发展的优劣势分析 来源:宣讲家网站报告发布时间:2011-03-15 03:12 增强机遇意识和忧患意识 十七届五中全会公报指出,我国的发展仍处于可以大有作为的战略机遇期。国际金融危机以后,中国的国际地位和影响力不是下降了而是上升了。在这个特殊的历史时期,全世界经济、政治格局重新洗牌,中国要集中精力把经济发展好,把社会建设好,进一步在国际舞台上寻找更大的发展机会。 现在我们到美国或欧洲去考察,会发现和30年前大不一样,和10年前都大不一样。我们到法国凡尔赛宫都有中文说明书, 10年前就没有,这说明中国到国外旅游的游客越来越多。上个世纪90年代以后,特别是21世纪以来,中国经济在发展,中国的各种文化、政治、经济的交流也在加强,中国到国外去的人越来越多。外国人也要为中国服务,重要的旅游景点、场所都要补上中文说明书,他们欢迎我们去学习、考察,说明中国的力量越来越大。 国际金融危机给中国提供一个重要的战略机遇期。国际经济格局、政治格局在调整,中国应该在这个伟大的历史性转折中抓住机会,有所作为。一是2010年我们经济总量已经超过日本,虽然人均GDP还很少,撵上美国还要好多年的历史。但是总的GDP能在全世界由过去的几十位上升到世界第二,这本身就是一件很大的事件。中国的地位也在上升,政治、经济、文化地位都在上升,给我们提供了大的机会。二是西方强势国家现在面临大的挑战,进入缓慢发展时期,这也给我们提供了发展机遇。三是亚非拉国家、非洲的发展中国家非常希望跟中国建立友好的关系,这对我国经济发展的长远稳定,包括我们和这些国家进行资源等方面的交流合作也创造一个好的条件,为我们争夺了更多的发展空间和战略空间。四是国际金融危机的影响很深远,整个全球经济出现大调整,围绕着市场、

中国近年来经济发展的现状及趋势

中国近年来经济发展的现状及趋势 进入21世纪之后,中国的经济环境有了很大的变化。从国 际形势看,欧元区国家的经济合作已经启动,但发展前景不明朗;美国自从经历“9.11”事件之后本国经济陷入低迷,至今尚未全 面恢复;日本经济则长期低速徘徊.尽管我国政府采取了一系列 积极的措施,例如:正式加入WTO;推动APEC的发展和中国——东盟自由贸易区的发展;加强同中亚国家的合作等;但整体外部形势依然严峻。这就需要我们从内部经济入手,找到推动经济增长的有效方法和途径。在国内经济中,由于存在众多的问题,无法一一列举,所以本文试图从通货膨胀、失业、GDP的增长几个方面来探讨影响中国经济的原因,并且试图找出解决问题的方法和途径。 一、对三条曲线的复合与分析 (一)三条曲线在一个坐标系中的复合:图一(% (二)三条曲线各自特点的分析 A、GDP增长率曲线 1、曲线走势:最近中国十几年的GDP增长率变动呈现前快后慢的特点。在第一个阶段,1991——1996年,GDP增长保持在一个较高的水平,平均达到11.6%;而在第二个阶段,1997——2001年间,GDP增长保持平稳中速的增长趋势,平均达到 7.8%。前后两个阶段平均增长率差异较大,呈现出比较明显的 阶段性特点。 2、原因

1)、1991——1996年的经济高速增长主要是基于以下方面: 第一,经历了二十世纪八十年代末的经济衰退,当时称之为“市 场疲软”之后,中央政府采取了一系列积极的财政、货币政策, 推动了经济的快速增长;第二,邓小平同志的南巡,一方面澄清 了许多人认识上的误区,另一方面,他以个人的远见,在宏观上 为中国创造了一种宽松、积极的氛围,加速了经济的增长。 2)、1997——2001年经济增速下降,主要是以下原因:首先,在经历了1991——1996年的经济高速增长之后,一些经济指标过热,造成诸如通货膨胀水平过高等方面的问题。所以国家在宏观上需要执行一套稳健、收缩的财政、货币政策。其次,1997年爆发的亚洲金融危机虽然没有对我国经济造成直接破坏,但也严重地影响了我国的整体外贸环境。重要表现之一就是传统东南亚国家进口市场的缩小,外贸行业整体效益的下滑,对我们这个外贸依存度非常高的国家来说,对经济增速的下降造成了实际的 压力。第三,为了适应经济全球化和加入WTO的要求,我国陆续开放了一批部门和行业,大力下调平均关税水平;这一系列的举措使国内原本受到很大程度保护的许多产业顿时感受到巨大 的压力,使得这些传统上的经济增长点在实际推动经济增长时显 得力不从心。 B、通货膨胀水平曲线 1、曲线走势:1992——2001年中国通货膨胀水平呈现先 高后低、先正后负的情况,同样具有阶段性的特点。1992——1996年间,平均商品零售物价指数保持在12.2%,而1997——2001年其平均水平仅为-0.6%。两个阶段相差13%,这种有趣的现象非常值得我们研究。 2、原因

建设中国特色社会主义论文

论建设中国特色社会主义 中国特色的社会主义,是在党的领导下根据中国的国情实行的社会主义,它应具有五个基本特征: 一、以民为本——是中国特色社会主义的出发点和落脚点 “以民为本”,就是以人民为本位”。我国宪法规定:“中华人民共和国的一切权力属于人民。"江泽民同志曾号召各级领导干部要“深怀爱民之心,恪守为民之责,善谋富民之策,多办利民之事,更好地为广大人民群众服务。"所以,以人民为本位,一切权力属于人民,是中国特色社会主义的出发点和落脚点。 二、市场经济——是中国特色社会主义的经济运行基础 中国特色的社会主义,是要搞社会主义市场经济,建立社会主义市场经济体制,优化资源的配置,发挥市场经济的基础作用。 三、共同富裕——是中国特色社会主义的根本目的 小平同志指出,实现共同富裕是社会主义的本质要求,是广大人民的普遍愿望。共同富裕,第一有个先富后富的问题,不可能大家同步富裕;第二即使大家共同富了,还应是有差别的,不搞平均主义,不然社会经济的发展就没有了动力。贫穷不是社会主义,平均主义也不是社会主义。我们实现共同富裕,要实行生产社会化和劳动者共同占有生产资料相结合。 四、中华文化——是中国特色社会主义的内在要求 一个民族,一个国家都有它自己的文化。我们中华民族有优秀的文化,应当继承发扬,同时要创新先进的文化,并吸收国外优秀的文化。 五、民主政治——是中国特色社会主义的重要保障 发展社会主义民主政治,是我们党始终不渝的奋斗目标,也是建设中国特色社会主义的重要保障。社会主义民主的本质是人民当家作主。依法治国的主体是广大人民。国家的一切权力属于人民,来源于人民,孟子说过:“民为贵,社稷次之,君为轻。”把加强对权力的监督和制约,作为依法治国的重要任务。 我国目前正处在社会主义的初级阶段,我们必须坚持不能离开社会主义。而且我们还处在初级阶段,我们必须从这个实际出发,而不能超越这个阶段。” (一)、这个阶段,是发展生产力的阶段。由于生产关系和上层建筑从不成熟,不完善到成熟和完备的发展,归根到底取决于生产力的发展,因此,生产力的落后是最基本的特征。 (二)、这个阶段,是发展经济的阶段。过去,我们越过商品经济的发展和市场化程度的提高,去建设社会主义,结果极大地妨碍了社会主义建设的顺利进行。现在我们努力改变这种状况,实现生产商品化,市场化,社会化,现代化。

浅谈当前中国经济发展所需面对的问题

浅谈当前中国经济发展所需面对的问题改革开放以来,中国经济持续高速发展,中国人民生活水平普遍提高,中国国际地位显著提高,综合国力大幅提升。然而,不可忽视的是随之而来的一系列等待处理的问题: 1、资源浪费与环境污染问题 过去我国长期实行的是粗放型经济增长方式,靠消耗资源、牺牲环境为代价来拉动经济增长。再加上在发展过程中,资源没有得到合理的利用,浪费现象普遍存在。因此时至今日,资源浪费和环境恶化问题也接踵而来。很多地方都因为环境问题而造成巨大损失,因此当我们在强调经济效益的同时,还应注重社会和环境效益,走可持续发展之路。 2、产业结构不合理的问题 我国农业基础薄弱,制造业大而不强,服务业发展滞后。我国经济增长主要依靠第二产业带动的格局没有根本性转变。 3、区域发展不平衡问题 改革开放后, 我国地区发展不平衡呈现出不断加剧的局面。城乡收入差距逐年扩大,调查显示中国农业从业者的收入增幅一直在下降,粮食产品价格下降,即使收成增产了,但收入却不见增加,地方政府对城市经济发展的重视程度远远大于对农业的关注。另外,行业收入差距的扩大,贫富差距问题的深化,造成的社会分配不公平现象的剧增,也令社会不稳定的因素有所增加。除此之外,我国东中西部发展差距也较大。 4、就业和失业问题 中国是个经济大国,同时也是个人口大国。虽然我国GDP水平已达世界前列,但人均GDP 水平在世界上始终居于落后位置。就业问题也一直是我国经济和社会发展的重大问题。受人民币升值,取消出口退税与实行紧缩货币政策的负面效应影响,沿海地区大量出口企业倒闭,金融危机爆发后情势进一步恶化。企业用工需求急剧下滑、现有就业岗位流失严重,失业数量骤增。再加上近年来高校扩招,大学生数目激增,求职者供过于求的现象,致使我国的就业问题进一步恶化。除此之外,我国人才和劳动力市场不规范,以及我国职业教育和培训工作相对滞后,这都加大了我国的就业压力。 这些都是中国发展壮大过程中不可避免的问题,只有正确处理好这些问题,我国经济才可以持续、快速、健康地发展,实现中华民族的伟大复兴。 然而,在经济高速发展的背后,同样存在着不少隐患: 1、通货膨胀压力明显偏大 目前,中国CPI涨幅虽有所回落但仍在上涨,而工业品出厂价格处于历史高位,价格上涨的压力尚未根本缓解。同时,一些地区和行业增长速度出现回落,

如何建设中国特色社会主义文化

毛泽东思想和中国特色社会主义理论体系概论题目:如何建设中国特色社会主义文化 院系:计算机科学与信息工程学院 班级:09网络工程一班 姓名: 学号:

如何建设中国特色社会主义文化 文化是一个内涵十分丰富的范畴,体现一个社会发展进程的重要标志,每一个朝代,每一种社会制度必然有属于它特有的文化属性,中国在经历历史的漫漫长路和近代的风雨坎坷与探索之路后最终建立起中国特有的文化体系。中国特色社会主义文化是建立在中国特色社会主义市场经济与政治基础上的,是社会主义事业的重要组成部分,推动社会主义文化大发展大繁荣,是社会主义社会全面发展的必然要求。 自共产党成立以来,党和国家领导人历来都十分重视文化的建设,毛泽东提出把旧文化统治而落后的中国建设成一个被新文化统治因而文明的中国,邓小平在改革开放的新时期创造性的阐述了关于社会主义精神文明建设的思想,他指出,社会主义精神文明是社会主义社会的重要特征,要在建设高度的物质文明的同时,建设高度的社会主义精神文明,从而构建中国特色的社会主义。党的十三届四中全会以来,党对精神文明建设和文化建设规律的认识不断深化,江泽民指出坚持以科学的理论武装人,以高尚的精神塑造人,以优秀的作品鼓舞人,中国特色社会主义文化是综合国力的重要标志,建设中国特色社会主义文化,就是以马克思主义为指导,以培养有理想、有道德、有文化、有纪律的公民为根本任务,发展面向现代化、面向世界、面向未来的,民族的科学的大众的社会主义文化。进入小康社会的新阶段,胡锦涛同志把文化建设摆在更加突出的位置,强调要牢牢把握社会主义先进文化的前进方向,兴起社会主义文化建设的新高潮 九十年来,我们党把马克思主义同我国建设的实际相结合,形成了关于文化建设的一系列重要的理论成果,创造性地丰富和发展了马克思主义文化理论。在当代中国,发展社会主义先进文化,建设和谐文化,就是建设中国特色社会主义文化。中国特色社会主义文化,就其主义内容来说,同改革开放以来我们一贯倡导的社会主义精神文明是一致的。要实现我国社会主义现代化建设和中华民族伟大复兴的宏伟目标,必须牢牢把握社会主义先进文化的前进方向,努力建设中国特设社会主义文化。 中国社会主义文化建设的根本任务就是以马克思列宁主义、毛泽东思想、邓

当前中国经济现状及未来形势

当前中国经济现状及未来形势 多数中国的经济学家认为,无论是从GDP的增长、固定资产投资还是工业生产的增长来看,中国经济基本上已经呈现比较明显的回落趋势,宏观调控效果明显。但是,根据谢国忠等人的分析,官方公布的GDP数据似乎与经济的总体表现不一致:三季度固定资产比上季度增长了%;商品贸易余额比上季度增加了104亿美元;M2供应量再次回升;人民币新增贷款加速增长;工业生产减速也很有限.过度投资、盲目建设、低水平重复建设的不良反应开始出现,主要是企业拖欠贷款、产成品积压等问题。鉴于此,要说中国经济已经实现了软着陆还为时过早。 因此,为了避免出现新一轮的经济过热,宏观调控的力度不能放松。 中国经济减速有限 GDP数据似乎表明今年中国经济会实现软着陆。2004年三季度GDP增长率为%,比预期的略高,但比2004年二季度和2004年一季度的%和%已有所下降。截止到目前,中国GDP年增长率为%,但仍远远高于过去五年平均8%的水平。鉴于上两个季度经济增长减速不明显,在我们看来,紧缩政策的效果有限,明年出现硬着陆的可能性增加。由于官方对去年GDP数据进行了向上修正,从%修正为%,我们调低了2004年GDP增长率的预期,从%下调至%。但对2005年的预测保持不变,GDP增长率仍为7%。 从名义值来看,2004年三季度GDP总计为万亿人民币,年增长率达到%,比二季度放慢了个百分点。然而,官方公布的名义增长率似乎与三季度的经济总体表现不一致:1)2004年三季度固定资产投资比上季度增长了个百分点,零售业仅下降了个百分点;2)三季度商品贸易余额达到了115亿美元,而二季度时仅为11亿美元,因此,四季度企业收入应会大幅增长。 再来看看三季度的工业情况,第一产业实际增长率为%,大概是自1990年以来增长最强劲的一个季度,主要原因是中央政府实行了农业改革政策。同时,三季度服务业增长率从二季度的%加速至%。但是,三季度制造业和建筑业总体增长率从二季度的%下降到%。 最新经济数据显示紧缩政策效果有限

中国特色社会主义社会建设

中国特色社会主义社会建设 一、中国特色社会主义社会建设概述 推进中国特色社会主义社会建设,必须从维护最广大人民根本利益和实现国家长治久安的战略高度抓好社会建设,努力构建社会主义和谐社会。 1. 社会建设 "社会建设"在不同语境下有不同含义。我们通常所说的社会建设,是指与经济、政治、文化建设相适应的社会建设。中国特色社会主义社会建设,就是以保障和改善民生为重点,通过发展社会事业、完善社会政策、改进社会管理、增强社会创造活力、促进社会公平正义、维护社会秩序等来推动社会的发展和进步。对于社会建设的认识,有一个逐步深化过程。改革开放以后,党和国家的工作重点转移到"以经济建设为中心"上来"经济建设"成为家喻户晓、耳熟能详的概念。但在经济建设的同时,经济社会协调发展的问题在实践中变得越来越重要。1982 年全国人大五届五次会议决定,从第六个五年计划开始,((国民经济五年计划》易名为《国民经济和社会发展五年计划>> ,增加了"社会发展"内容。此后,人口、就业、社会保障、收入分配、卫生健康、科技教育、社会管理等社会发展的内容逐步充实。中共十六大提出全面建设小康社会的奋斗目标,增加了"社会更加和谐"这一国家建设的重要目标。 中共十六届四中全会明确提出"构建社会主义和谐社会"的任务和"社会建设"的概念,并把中国特色社会主义建设的总体布局,由原来的经济建设、政治建设、文化建设三位一体,变为包括社会建设在内的四位一体的新格局。中共十七大进一步对加快推进以改善民生为重点的社会建设进行全面部署,对社会建设的任务和政策进行了专章论述。伴随对社会建设认识的逐步深化,社会建设越来越成为各级政府的重要工作任务,成为理论研究的重要内容。 2. 中国特色社会主义社会建设理论内涵 中国特色社会主义社会建设理论的内涵十分丰富,涉及经济社会各个领域,涵盖社会建设各个方面,其基本点主要包括以下方面: (一)关于构建和谐社会的思想。社会和谐是社会主义的本质属性。要按照民主法治、公平正义、诚信友爱、充满活力、安定有序、人与自然和谐相处的总要求,努力构建全体人民共同建设、共同享有的和谐社会。着眼于促进经济社会协调发展,把社会主义和谐社会建设同社会主义经济建设、政治建设、文化建设和生态文明建设一起,作为中国特色社会主义事业总体布局的重要组成部分统一部署、整体推进。 (二)关于保障和改善民生的思想。社会建设以最广大人民群众的根本利益为

当前中国经济发展形势.

当前中国经济发展形势 内容提要:我国经济发展面临着巨大的挑战,同时面临着众多的问题,不仅面临着世界的巨大问题与挑战也面临着国内和国内各区域的问题,这些问题阻碍着我我国经济发展的步伐,幸好我国有着良好的经济前景,因此我国对相应问题提出了相应的政策以保证我国的经济又好又快的发展。 关键词:发展问题/对策 虽然中国经济改革和制度转型是通过由易到难、由浅入深、由农村到城市、由体制外到体制内的改革方式使得中国的经济增长与发展、经济效率的改进和人们生活水平的提高在过去20年中取得了很大的成绩,但近几年来,随着种种原因,已呈现出比较明显的通货紧缩现象。导致经济低迷既有经济周期和盲目投资造成的生产能力过剩、消费。心理倾向发生变化所引起的需求疲软、外部经济环境恶化导致的出口下降这些原因,也有经济体制软件落后及经济体制硬件结构的不合理使得经济增长后劲不足的原因。要解决这些问题,必须在财政政策和货币政策与民众预期收入信心不足的措施相互配套、刺激广大民众的消费需求的同时,采用各种刺激企业(特别是非国有企业)的投资热情及扩大外贸出口等措施尽量给予人们经济自主权,尽量减少政府干预经济的活动。只有这样,才能达到解决经济低迷的事半功倍的效果,促使经济持续性长久发展。 经济发展是一个综合问题,受多方面因素影响,在不同的环境下,不同的时间下,起基本作用的因素是不同的。当今中国的经济面临的挑战也是有目共睹的。 第一个挑战就是资源的挑战。我们的各类矿产资源、能源、包括水资源,都是非常紧缺的。我们现在铁矿石基本上进口一半;我们原油进口接近1亿吨,已经超过了日本,居全世界第二,仅次于美国。要应对资源的挑战,包括水资源的挑战、矿产资源的挑战、能源的挑战,中国将来一定要发展节约型的经济。我们曾经说了很多建立节约型经济的思路,比如我说过中国应该提倡住比较小的公寓,比如三口之家,住100平方米就可以了,因为你的公寓冬天要烧暖气,夏天要用空调,要排放,但现在全国各大城市的建筑趋势和老百姓的住房需求是远远超过这个标准的,这是令人担心的。要看看日本人是怎么生活的,日本人的生活方式是怎么样的,要舒适,但要比较小。可以建设停车场、电梯,但公寓本身都是比较小的 第二个挑战,中国目前有很多的经济学家认为中国的贫富差距过大,比如中国基尼系数已经非常高了,达到0.45了。我认为对这个问题要重视。但是我觉得目前中国的贫富差距主要是在城乡的差别,而城乡的差别主要在于城市的各个要素已经货币化了,而农村没有。如果你按购买力平价,按照农村生活质量来算,中国实际上的贫富差距没有这么大,实际上我们的基尼系数没有那么高。这是非常重要的问题,已经有的人在大声疾呼,发表一些耸人听闻的言论。我们一方面要注意它,但一方面要看到中国基尼系数计算出来比较高,主要是

中国产业经济发展历程、发展现状以及未来发展趋势

中国产业经济发展历程、发展现状以及未来发展趋势 产业,简而言之,即是具有某种同类属性的具有相互作用的经济活动组成的集合或系统。产业经济学研究的是产业内部各企业之间相互作用关系的规律、产业本身的发展规律、产业与产业之间互动联系的规律以及产业在空间区域中的分布规律等等,这些都是产业经济学研究的具体对象。产业经济学是一门新兴的综合性、应用性很强的经济学科。它以“产业”为研究对象,研究产业的形成、发展和调整,也研究和分析产业内企业之间的市场竞争关系。它既涉及了偏向宏观的经济问题研究,如产业布局、产业结构的调整与升级等;也涉及微观经济问题的分析,如企业的定价理论、企业的兼并、技术创新等。产业经济学的研究对象在欧美产业经济学中即为产业组织,研究的是市场运行,主要关注企业行为,其与市场结构和市场演变过程具有密切关系,涉及相关的公共政策。我国50年代受苏联的影响,产业主要指计划经济中的行业和部门,没有明确的产业经济学名称。改革开放后受日本的影响,强调产业结构和产业政策。80年代末,欧美主流的产业组织理论引入中国,使得以产业组织和公共政策为主的欧美和以产业结构与政策为主的日本体系相结合。针对产业经济本身所具有的不同层次的具体行为规律,产业经济学又有不同的具体研究对象,包括产业组织、产业结构、产业关联、产业布局、产业发展、产业政策等等。 研究产业经济学,有利于建立有效的产业组织结构通过对产业经济学的研究,可以探求过度竞争或有效竞争不足的形成途径及消除方式;发现规模经济的形成原因及优点等等,从而根据不同的产业,分别制定正确的产业组织政策。研究产业经济学也有利于有效的产业组织的形成以及产业结构的优化,产业结构的合理均衡是国民经济健康发展的前提,而产业结构的升级则更是国民经济迅速发展的必由之路。寻找产业结构不合理的成因,并以此制定有效的产业结构政策、调整产业的结构,也是研究产业经济学的意义所在。进一步而言,研究产业经济学,探寻产业升级的规律和带动经济起飞的主导产业,利用合理的产业政策加以保护和扶持,便可以实现产业结构向更高的水平演进,以增强整体产业的国际竞争力,促进经济的发展。寻找产业合理布局的基本原则也是促使产业经济学研究进一步深入的动力之一。通过产业经济学的研究,可以探求产业布局的影响因素、产业布局的一般规律,并据此制定正确的产业布局政策,实现产业布局的合理化。研究产业经济学也是产业政策实践的需要。通过产业经济学的研究,还有利于加强产业间的联系、发挥产业的协同效益,以及有利于确定合理的产业发展战略。 从理论上研究产业经济学,它的历史演进及流派大致经历三个阶段,形成了三个主要流派——哈佛学派,又被称为“结构主义学派”、芝加哥学派,又被称为“效率主义”、新产业组织理论,被称为“行为主义”。前两者以传统理论为基础,因此也称传统产业组织理论。产业经济学萌芽于英国,但完整的理论框架形成于美国。20世纪30年代,垄断乃至寡头发展,卡特尔、托拉斯等垄断组织普遍,垄断问题引起广泛讨论。在利用马歇尔冲突成果的基础上,斯拉法将马氏的垄断分析深化为不完全竞争理论、论述了规模经济与完全竞争的不相容性,即“斯拉法冲突”。随后,张伯伦和罗宾逊夫人进一步丰富了垄断竞争理论。哈佛大学梅森和其学生贝恩最早在哈佛开设产业经济学课程,哈佛成为产业经济学的研究中心,创立了哈佛学派。哈佛学派的产业组织理论以张伯伦的垄断竞争理论为基础,用结构—行为—绩效(SCP)分析方法来对特定产业进行分析,从而规范了产业组织的理论体系。从70年代后期开始哈佛学派受到了严厉批评。在这一过程中,芝加哥大学以施蒂格勒为代表的一些学者等对哈佛学派的观点展开了激烈抨击,并逐渐形成了一种新的产业组织理论核心——芝加哥学派。芝加哥学派对哈佛学派的批评包括对张伯伦的垄断竞争理论的批评。进入20世纪70年代,与前两个学派不同,新产业经济学派即不同意哈佛学派的观点,也不同意芝加哥学派的观点。因为哈佛学派所依据的关于垄断竞争的理论是有问题的,因为他们认为垄断

中国特色社会主义社会建设

一、中国特色社会主义社会建设理论中国特色社会主义社会建设是一个系统工程,既涉及基本理论问题,又涉及建设任务和管理问题,这都是中国特色社会主义社会建设的理论问题。 1.中国特色社会主义社会建设的基本理论, 中国特色社会主义社会建设理论的内涵十分丰富,涉及经济社会各个领域,涵盖社会建设各个方面,其基本点主要包括以下方面: 一是构建和谐社会的理论。社会和谐是中国特色社会主义的 本质属性。要按照民主法治、公平正义、诚信友爱、充满活力、安定有序、人与自然和谐相处的总要求,努力构建全体人民共同建设、共同享有的和谐社会。构建社会主义和谐社会必须坚持以人为本,坚持科学发展,坚持改革开放,坚持民主法治,坚持正确处理改革发展稳定的关系,坚持在党的领导下全社会共同建设。着眼于促进经济社会协调发展,把社会主义和谐社会建设同社会主义经济建设、政治建设、文化建设和生态文明建设一起,作为中国特色社会主义事业总体布局的重要组成部分统一部署、整体推进。 二是保障和改善民生的理论。保障和改善民生是社会建设的重点。提髙人民的物质文化生活水平, 是改革开放和社会主义现代化建设的根本目的。社会主义事业是代表最广大人民 根本利益的事业,社会主义民生事业是实现最广大人民群众根本利益的事业。要 始终站在最广大人民的立场上,着力解决好人民最关心最直接最现实的利益问题, 最大限度地激发全社会的创造活力,努力使全体人民学有所教、劳有所得、病有 所医、老有所养、住有所居,推动建设和谐社会。 三是实现和维护社会公平正义的理论。在发展的基础上,实现和维护社会公平正义,是马 克思主义的基本立场和基本观点,是中国特色社会主义的内在要求。社会公平正义,就是 社会各方面的利益关系得到妥善协调,人民内部矛盾和其他社会矛盾得到正确处理,人民的合法权益得到切实维护和实现。实现社会公平正义,要在全体人民共 同奋斗、经济社会发展的基础上,加紧建设保障社会公平正义具有重大作用的制度, 逐步建立以权利公平、机会公平、规则公平为主要内容的社会法律和制度体系,努 力营造好的社会环境,保证人民平等参与、平等发展权利。社会公平正义的核心 是权利公平、机会公平和规则公平,其中权利公平是基础机会好是前提,规则公 平是保障,三者相辅相成,构成一个完整的现代社会公平正义体系。在经济发展 的基础上夯实社会公平正义的物质基础,在推进民主政治建设中维护和实现社会 公平正义,在公民意识教育中树立公平正观念’营造公平正义的社会环境。 四是促进城乡协调发展的理论。城乡协调发展是社会建的基础,正确认识和妥善处理工业和农业、城市和农村、城镇居民和农民的关系逐步解决城乡二元结构矛盾,努力实现城乡共同繁荣。加大统筹城乡发展力度,增强农村发展活力,逐步缩小城乡差距,促进城乡协调发展。坚持工业反哺农业、城市支持农村和多予少取放活方针,加大强农惠农富农政策力度,让广大农民平等参与现代化进程、共同分享现代化成果。加快完善城乡发展一体化体制机制,着力在城乡规划、基础设施、公共服务等方面推进一体化,促进城乡要素平等交换和公共资源均衡配置,形成以工促农、以城带乡、工农互惠、城乡一体的新型工农、城乡关系。不断深化对社会主义社会建设规律的认识’在社会主义现代化进程中,促进城乡共同繁荣和共同发展。 五是兼顾不同阶层利益的理论。兼顾不同阶层利益是社会建设的关键。在中国,包括知识分子在内的工人阶级以及广大农民,始终是推动中国先进生产力和社会全面进步的根本力量。在社会变革中出现的民营科技企业的创业人员和技术人员、受聘于外资企业的管理技术人员、个体户、私营企业主、中介组织的从业人员、自由职业人员等社会

浅谈对当今中国经济发展速度放缓

浅谈对当今中国经济发展速度放缓的认识 中国经济增长速度的连续放缓,引发国内外观察家的种种关注,其中不乏有人担忧其潜在的长远影响。而沉寂一段时间的中国经济崩溃论、危机论、硬着陆论、滞胀论等种种说法,也开始浮出水面。 这些担忧有没有道理?如何正确看待增速放缓?为何会出现增 速放缓?未来我国经济发展趋势怎样? 一、中国经济放缓缘由何故 中国经济现在最突出的问题,就是增长速度迅速回落,连续六个季度的GDP增长速度持续下行,已经从9.7%掉到7.6%。中国经济现在出现增速持续下行,大的原因是两个。 一个是我们出口受阻,整个实业经济衰退。我们没有认识到世界金融危机的长期性,忧患意识不足。中国的出口依存度为25%多一点,也就是说,这么庞大的经济,有四分之一和出口紧密相关。现在整个世界经济萎缩,我们不可能不受影响。今年我们的出口增长目标是10%,但是7月份是1%,我觉得今年的目标确实难以实现。中国这么庞大的经济体,其增长的根本点不可能也不应该放到外部需求里,所以我们要扩大内需。过去的增长方式是依赖低成本打天下。我们的经济结构、增长方式有问题,这些才是我们应该下大力气去解决的。只有解决了增长方式问题,中国经济才能保持持续增长。 第二个问题是我们自身的问题。拉动中国经济增长的三驾马车是投资、消费和出口。现在看来,这三驾马车全都遇到了新情况。除了出口这驾马车指望不上了外,消费长期不振,而现在投资这驾马车也出现了新问题。 那么怎么来看经济增速下行?应该把握三点。第一,一定要看到经济增速的适度下行不是坏事。“十六大”提出科学发展观的时候,讲了这么一句:“中国经济经过这么多年的发展,主要问题不是数量问题,还是质量问题、效益问题。”中国经济增长的数据还是偏快、偏热。

当前我国经济社会发展现状及前景展望

当前我国经济社会发展现状及前景展望我国经济形势正处在建国以来相对稳定、持续增长、经济效益明显改善、生态环境效益开始改善的良好时期。我国经济增长模式正在经历明显的转变,根据数据表明“九五”期间比“八五”期间年平均GDP增长率有所下降,但经济增长质量和经济效益明显好于“八五”期间。中共十四届五中全会提出“积极推进经济增长方式转变,把提高经济效益作为经济工作的中心,从粗放型向集约型转变。”大量数据表明,中国经济增长模式正在发生明显转变,正在从数量扩张型向质量改善型转变,不仅经济效益改善,而且环境生态效益开始改善。但是我们不能盲目追求高经济增长率,我们希望经济增长率是没有水分的、实实在在的、有经济效益的经济增长率。因此,从国际横向比较看,尽管近年来中国经济增长率呈减缓趋势,但仍然是全球经济增长率最高的国家之一,也是宏观经济比较稳定的国家之一,已经成为东亚地区经济增长和贸易增长的发动机与经济稳定的“稳定器”。由于受金融危机和全球经济与贸易衰退的影响,很多发达国家经济都受到了很大的影响,只有中国和印度避免了这种情形。 虽然我国在稳步发展中,但是也存在了不少问题。首先,我国正在经历有史以来最大规模的经济结构调整,因此面临大规模、突发性的“下岗洪水”、“失业洪水”,这已成为了我国目前最突出的问题。因此,安抚好失业人群是社会稳定的重要基础。面对大规模结构调整和失业,国家大量增加社会保障资金,支付结构改革成本,购买社会稳定。其次,“三农”问题是中国经济发展的首要问题。“三农”问题

的核心是广大农民的农业收入的绝对数大幅度下降,而农民无法大规模地向非农产业和城镇转移,因此,扩大内需主要是要提高居民的消费需求;而提高居民消费主要是提高广大农民的消费需求;要提高农民的消费需求,必须要提高农民人均收入水平;要提高农民人均收入,则必需提高农民人均工资性收入。只有解放农民、投资农民、转移农民、减少农民才有可能富裕农民。 我国有着很强的发展前景,首先经济中长期增长潜力仍然巨大。我们既有巨大的市场需求和发展空间,又有比较充分的发展要素供给条件。居民消费结构由温饱型向小康型升级,创造了新的市场最终需求。城市化进程加快,使我国经济在国际竞争中处于比较有利的地位。其次,投资与消费关系应当逐步得到合理调整,人民群众将从经济增长中得到更多实惠。影响我国投资和消费关系变化的主要因素有:居民收入水平提高和消费结构升级,需要进一步拓展居民消费的空间。在投资和消费关系的合理变动中,城乡居民人均收入将持续增长,恩格尔系数将进一步下降,人民生活水平有较大提高,生活质量将进一步改善。第三,分阶段基本实现工业化,并使城市化水平显著提高。这是我国全面建成小康社会的两个重要目标,也是传统二元经济结构向现代经济结构转换的鲜明标志。这两个目标一旦实现,将是中华民族发展史上的又一个重大里程碑。第四,经济增长方式转换应当取得重大进展。随着各项改革的深化和技术进步,我国经济增长方式由粗放型向集约型进一步转变,有可能具备比过去更为有利的体制条件和物质技术基础。但任务仍然十分艰巨,经过“十一五”期间乃至更长时

中国经济社会发展战略的目标和步骤

中国经济社会发展战略的目标和步骤 (一)我国经济社会发展的战略目标 实现社会主义现代化是巩固社会主义制度的内在要求。社会主义现代化是社会的全面进步。它既要实现经济的现代化,达到富强的目标;还要提高全民族的文化素质,发展高尚的、丰富的精神文化生活,达到文明的目标。我国社会主义初级阶段社会经济发展的战略目标是:到21世纪中叶,把我国建设成为富强、民主、文明的社会主义现代化国家,基本实现现代化。 我国社会主义现代化建设总体目标的三个重要方面是相互作用、相互联系的。实现富强,是为了提高人民的生活水平,是实现民主和文明的物质基础;实现民主,是为了调动人民群众的积极性,它是发展生产力的重要社会条件;实现文明,既为物质进步提供精神动力和智力支持,又为社会主义民主的发展提供精神文化条件。 (二)分"三步走"的战略步骤★★(多选) 邓小平在总结我国以往发展战略经验教训的基础上,提出了"三步走"的发展战略,即基本实现现代化的台阶式发展战略:第一步,从1981年到1990年国民生产总值翻一番,解决人民温饱问题;第二步,从1991年到20世纪末国民生产总值再翻一番,人民生活达到小康;第三步,到21世纪中叶,人均国民生产总值达到中等发达国家水平,人民生活比较富裕,基本实现现代化。然后在这个基础上继续前进。 经过上个世纪80年代以来三个五年计划的努力,原定到2000年国民生产总值比1980年翻两番的任务已于1995年提前完成。 (三)21世纪头20年,全面建设小康社会的奋斗目标★★★(多选) 江泽民同志在党的十六大报告中提出了在新世纪头20年全面建设小康社会的奋斗目标和继续完成社会主义现代化任务的"新三步走"战略。"新三步走"战略步骤是指:从2000年到2010年国内生产总值翻一番,人口控制在14亿以内,人民生活更加宽裕,形成比较完善的社会主义市场经济体制;2020年比2010年再翻一番,全面建成小康社会(2003年第27题:"中国共产党的十六大报告提出的全面建设小康社会的目标",多选题)。第三步,从2020年到21世纪中叶,基本实现现代化,达到发达国家的中等水平。本世纪头20年我国的目标是:全面建设小康社会. 全面建设小康社会的奋斗目标是: --经济建设与改革的目标。以优化结构和提高效益为基础,我国的综合实力和国际竞争力明显增强。到2020年,我国国内生产总值力争比2000年翻两番,综合国力和国际竞争力明显增强。基本实现工业化,建成完善的社会主义市场经济体制和具有活力、更加开放的经济体系。城镇人口的比重较大幅度提高,工农差别、城乡差别和地区差别扩大的趋势逐步扭转。社会保障体系比较健全,社会就业比较充分,家庭财产普遍增加,人民过上更加富足的生活。 --民主政治建设的目标。社会主义民主更加完善,社会主义法制更加完备,依法治国基本方略得到全面落实,人民的政治、经济和文化权益得到切实尊重和保障。基层民主更加健全,社会秩序良好,人民安居乐业。 --精神文明建设的目标。全民族的思想道德素质、科学文化素质和健康素质明显提高,形成比较完善的国民教育体系、科技和文化创新体系、全民健身和医疗卫生体系。人民享有接受良好教育的机会,基本普及高中阶段教育,扫除文盲。形成全民学习、终身学习的学习型社会,促进人的全面发展。 --实现可持续发展的目标。可持续发展能力不断增强,生态环境得到改善,资源利用效率显著提高,促进人与自然的和谐,推动整个社会走上生产发展、生活富裕、生态良好的文明发展道路。 全面建设小康社会,是我国在本世纪头20年的奋斗目标。这一目标是中国特色社会主义

相关文档
最新文档