An Analysis of the Financial Crisis of 2008 Causes and Solutions

An Analysis of the Financial Crisis of 2008 Causes and Solutions
An Analysis of the Financial Crisis of 2008 Causes and Solutions

Abstract

This research evaluates the fundamental causes of the current financial crisis. Close financial analysis indicates that theoretical modeling based on unrealistic assumptions led to serious problems in mispricing in the massive unregulated market for credit default swaps that exploded upon catalytic rises in residential mortgage defaults. Recent academic research implies solutions to the crisis that are appraised to be far less costly than a bailout of investors who made poor financial decisions with respect to credit analysis. JEL: G11, G12, G13, G14

________________________________________________________________________ *by Austin Murphy, Professor of Finance, Oakland University, SBA, Rochester, MI 48309-4493 (248-370-2125; jamurphy@https://www.360docs.net/doc/fd11015586.html,).

The financial crisis in 2008 is of such epic proportions that even astronomical amounts spent to address the problem have so far been insufficient to resolve it. Besides the well-publicized $700 billion approved by Congress, the Federal Reserve has attempted to bail out institutions and markets with about $1.3 trillion in investments in various risky assets, including loans to otherwise bankrupt institutions and collateralized debt obligations like those backed by subprime mortgages that are defaulting at rapid rates (Morris, 2008). A further $900 billion is being proposed in lending to large corporations (Aversa, 2008), making a total of nearly $3 trillion in bailout money so far, without even counting the massive sum of corporate debts guaranteed by the U.S. government in the last year. An analysis of the fundamental causes of this “colossal failure” that has put “the entire financial system… at risk” (Woellert and Kopecki, 2008) is warranted in order to both solve the problem and avoid such events in the future.

Root Cause of the Crisis: Mispricing in the Massive Credit Default Swaps Market Many blame defaulting mortgages for the current financial crisis, but this massive tragedy is only a component and symptom of the deeper problem. The pricing of credit default swaps, whose principal amount has been estimated to be $55 by the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and may actually exceed $60 trillion (or over 4 times the publicly traded corporate and mortgage U.S. debt they are supposed to insure), are totally unregulated, and have often been contracted over the phone without documentation

(Simon, 2008), is the primary fundamental issue from which all the other problems of the crisis emanate.

Credit default swaps are actually rather simple instruments in concept, merely mandating that one party paying a periodic fee to another to insure the debts of some entity (such as a specified corporation) against default for a particular amount of time like 5 years. They are effectively debt insurance policies that are labeled otherwise to avoid the regulation that normally is imposed on insurance contracts. This unregulated market grew astronomically from $900 billion at the turn of the millennium to over $50 trillion in 2008 after Congress enacted a law exempting them from state gaming laws in 2000 (PIA Connection, 2008)..

Any investment in a debt requires compensation not only for the time value of money but also a premium for the credit risk of the debt. Compensation for the time value of money is usually provided by the debt promising, at a minimum, a yield equal to that of the rate available on default-free government securities like U.S. Treasury bonds. The credit risk premium above that rate must compensate investors for not only the expected value of default losses but also for the systematic risk relating to the debt, as well as for any embedded options (Murphy, 1988).

In a credit default swap or bond insurance contract, there is no initial investment in the debt by the insuring party, and so only a credit risk premium is required. This premium must, however, include both the default risk premium and the systematic risk premium. Appropriate appraisal methods for estimating those premiums have long been known (Callaghan and Murphy, 1998).

However, many practitioners today apply pure mathematical theories to evaluate credit risk and estimate credit risk premiums to be required (Glantz and Mun, 2008). The models of such “’quants’ who have wielded so much influence over modern banking” are often “worse than useless” (NewScientist, 2008b). Some investors in debt securities look only at the credit ratings provided by a few rating agencies such as Moody’s and Standard & Poors (S&P), which themselves evaluate credit using such models. Those models, which use statistics to uncover past relationships between debt defaults and a few variables, as in the seminal Altman (1968) study, can ignore very important factors and possibilities (Woellert and Kopecki, 2008). While some have suggested that the models only need to be improved (NewScientist, 2008b), all statistical models are subject to the problems of spurious correlations between variables that are magnified as the number of variables are increased, and so it is questionable whether credit analysis can ever be conducted without some human judgment.

Existing mathematical credit risk models have “a tendency to underestimate the likelihood of sudden large events” (Buchanan, 2008) that are especially important in the credit markets where the tail of a distribution is key in predicting the defaults that typically have a low probability of occurrence (Murphy, 2000). The mathematical models typically fail to consider inter-related systematic risks (Jameson, 2008), and they tend to make unrealistic assumptions such as markets always being in equilibrium (NewScientist, 2008a). Despite their “poor risk modeling” in actuality (Jameson, 2008), the statistical accuracy of the models in predicting backward into the past (using historic data) resulted in the mathematical modelers developing such a “faith in their models” in forecasting the

future that they began to “to ignore what was happening in the real world” (NewScientist, 2008b).

In addition, without human judgment, financial models of credit risk are subject to manipulation, both legally and fraudulently. Just for instance, the modeling predictions at the rating agencies have, at least recently, been biased toward granting higher ratings than merited in order to compete for revenues from the debtors who pay to be rated and are a “colossal failure” (Burns, 2008). The result has been that a large portion of the credit default swaps were mispriced.

The mortgage crisis itself may have largely been caused by the mispricing of credit default swaps. A major contributor to the lack of subjective judgment and verification of the model inputs was the fact that mortgage brokers were motivated by loan origination commissions to just maximize the volume of issued mortgages that often required no money down and no proof of income because the risks associated with such lending policies were “blurred” to the final investors who took positions in them through collateralized debt obligations or CDOs (Buchanan, 2008). One factor causing CDO investors to accept such uncertainties may very well have been that such mortgage-backed securities were widely insured against losses from default by insurers like AIG, which itself placed “blind faith in financial risk models” and their small elite staff of modelers who initially generated large income for the firm that later turned into decimating losses (Morgenson, 2008). AIG’s modelers likely justified their pricing by applying purely statistical credit scoring procedures using a limited number of factors that didn’t incorporate the effects of requiring no documentation for the inputs to the models

and having no human credit analyst to provide a subjective judgment. In many cases, the unverified inputs to the models were even widely recognized to be false or misleading.1 In addition, many of the more sophisticated mathematical models of debt instruments were based on theories that implied the systematic risks of debts could be hedged or diversified away (Duffee, 1999). As a result, many modelers questioned the need to require any yield compensation for systematic risks (Elton, Gruber, Agrawal, and Mann, 2001) that debt investors normally receive because the risks of debt investments can’t be fully diversified away (Murphy, 2000). Unfortunately, the theories that indicate debt investors only need to charge sufficient interest to cover expected default losses are based on unrealistic assumptions, such as no transaction costs and a continuous distribution of returns (Merton, 1974). As a result, their conclusions are invalid despite the accuracy of their mathematics.

Such modeling procedures resulted in many credit default swaps being priced to have the periodic payment compensate the insuring party for average default losses. Without the extra yield cushion that normally is required to cover the systematically above-average default losses that inevitably occur in some years, debt investors had set themselves up for large losses at some point. With many of the insuring parties of credit default swaps being banks and other financial institutions that were highly leveraged with large current obligations, suffering losses created the risk of these insurers defaulting on their own obligations under the credit default swaps,2 leading to a potential domino effect on their swap counterparties and a systematic cascade of defaults.

Compounding the problem of failing to charge a systematic risk premium in the credit default swaps was the previously mentioned problem of underestimating even average default losses because of the failure to utilize subjective human judgment in the statistical modeling of default risk. The result was that the payments on credit default swaps didn’t even cover future default losses in average years.

Such under-pricing of credit default swaps resulted in a credit bubble, as investors hedged their debt investments with the insurance of the credit default swaps to reduce their risk at abnormally low costs and drive up debt prices. As a result, investors were able to borrow at extremely low premiums to default-free U.S. Treasury rates for several years (as indicated by the very low spreads between Treasury yields and corporate debt yields, especially junk yields, until 2007 that were readily observed daily in the financial press like the Wall Street Journal).

For a while, the recipients of the periodic insurance payment on the credit default swaps were able to generate large profits from the contracts, as defaults were initially lower than the insurance payments. That situation was especially prevalent in the mortgage market because newly issued mortgages generally default at lower rates than more seasoned ones. In addition, many of the newly originated mortgages had adjustable rates that offered a low teaser payment for the first 1-5 years of the loan before they were contracted to rise according to a formula based on market rates of interest, and default rates naturally rise with such adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMs) over time. However, given that no systematic risk premium was being charged, and given that the default risk premium was less than the default losses that would be estimated by expert human credit

analysts, the profits were almost certain to turn into losses as soon as defaults rose to a more normal level.

The Foreclosure Catalyst

In fact, default losses on subprime mortgages began to exceed expected default losses in 2007. One of the reasons for the rise in mortgage defaults was the increase in interest rates charged on the loans that had been set at introductory teaser rates which were contractually raised to market levels after the introductory period (ranging between 1 and 5 years) expired. The resulting foreclosures brought an excess supply of homes onto the market that caused residential real estate prices to fall, contributing to further mortgage defaults. As the market value of mortgages fell, the viability of many banks and other financial institutions was called into question, resulting in a wholesale bank run that required the Federal Reserve to bailout the system with several hundred billion dollars in liquidity in the summer of 2007.

As investors began to perceive that defaults could spread beyond mortgages, the systematic risk premiums began to rise across all debt instruments, resulting in a fall in debt prices across the board. Systematically falling debt prices led to further increases in perceived systematic risk and further increases in systematic risk premiums in a cycle that brought us to the 2008 financial crisis.

The Liquidity Crisis

Exasperating the cycle along the way were the failures of several large financial institutions such as Bear Stearns, Freddie Mac,3 Fannie Mae, Lehman Brothers, and AIG. These failures were related to the investments of those institutions into debt contracts of various types that had fallen in value to the point where their liabilities exceeded the market value of their assets. In some cases, such as that of Bear Stearns, there was also a liquidity crisis, insofar as the market value of the liability of that investment bank on its massive portfolio of credit default swaps began to rise so much that the counterparty was able to demand additional collateral be put up as security against payment on the credit default swaps.4

A similar liquidity crisis later ensued at AIG, with that insurance company having insured a massive amount of collateralized mortgage obligations. As previously explained, much of the mortgage crisis may be attributed to AIG and other insurers of mortgage paper like AMBAC and MBNA. In particular, many of the subprime mortgages may never have been originated and packaged into pools if there hadn’t been an agreement by the insurance companies to guarantee the mortgage-backed securities with specified characteristics against default. The premiums charged on the credit default swaps do not appear to have provided sufficient compensation for the higher default rates on mortgages with lower (or no) down payments, especially when no documentation was required and no human credit analysis was undertaken.

The problem of under-pricing the insurance payments on credit default swaps may have been at least partially exasperated by the mathematical models of the insurers not fully allowing for the rising defaults that normally occur on adjustable rate mortgages as the interest rate rises following initially low teaser rates. Unrealistic expectations of

ever-rising home prices that would enable refinancing mortgages when the introductory teaser rates rose after a few years may have also contributed. Although the existence of evidence of a possible bubble top in real estate prices at that time (Shiller, 2005) would make the latter expectations appear to be especially implausible, AIG was able to record large profits from its insurance scheme until those higher default rates materialized (Morgenson, 2008).

As more institutions failed, market risk premiums rose ever further, leading to further calls for collateral on firms that were receiving the periodic payments on credit default swaps. The resulting liquidity squeeze can cause more defaults and market risk premiums rising ever farther in a vicious cycle without interventions by the Federal Reserve to supply needed cash. Nevertheless, despite the Fed’s massive efforts to date, credit risk premiums rose to over 8% on a leading index of credit default swaps (Moses and Harrington, 2008).

The Size of the Problem

Despite the enormous amount already spent by the federal government to bailout the financial markets, much more may be needed to save the system as it is. In particular, assuming the average debt for the $62 trillion in credit default swaps merited a Baa credit rating, and assuming credit risk premiums being charged that equaled only 2/3 that of the expected default losses on those credits, data provided in Murphy (2000) indicate that the contracted under-pricing was {{1/3}0.33%)+1.35%=1.46% per year. That comes to a market value loss of .0146x$62 trillion=$ per year, or about $5 trillion over the typical 5-

year life of a credit default swap. Those huge market value losses exist even though initially the premium of 0.22% on the credit default swaps may have exceeded the typical abnormally low default losses on ARMs shortly after origination. While there may have been some hedging or offsetting contracts that would reduce the scope of the cost of a full bailout, it is unclear how large an offset that would be.

In addition, it should also be mentioned that the premiums charged for the credit default swaps in no event covered the abnormally large default losses that periodically occur during recessions. With the financial crisis likely to result in such a downturn, the losses on the credit default swaps are likely to be even larger for the duration of that recession. That could easily raise the cost of a bailout by over $1 trillion per year of an economic slowdown. Since the very existence of the financial crisis may negatively affect the economy through reduced consumer spending (caused by the uncertainty) and decreased bank lending (caused by rising credit risk and credit risk premiums), such additional costs may be further magnified by a more severe and protracted recession. The total cost of the crisis could exceed $10 trillion.5

Possible Solutions to the Crisis

There are perhaps other solutions to the crisis besides a massive bailout of the markets. One simple policy would be to nationalize the depository institutions of the failed corporate holding companies, and simply let the holding companies and all other failed institutions go bankrupt and default on their credit default swaps. The nationalized banks could then go back to making loans as they did in the old days, having real human

beings make credit-granting decisions. The cost of this policy to taxpayers might be rather small, especially since most of the losses on the defaulting credit default swaps would either be offsetting or be incurred by investors like hedge funds.

For institutions suffering strictly from a liquidity crisis but having a firm value in excess of their liabilities, simple enforcement of the regulations on short sales might be of great assistance. In particular, as shown theoretically and empirically by Murphy, Callaghan, and Parkash (2005), companies with inadequate internal liquidity can have their stock price shorted down to zero and then be totally unable to access the capital markets, thereby resulting in the failure of the firm. To inhibit such shorting down of value, the illegal “naked” shorting that is concentrated in foreign markets but also goes on in the U.S. because of inadequate enforcement by clearing agents (Boni, 2006) could be prevented by having the SEC start to enforce the laws requiring delivery of borrowed shares by short sellers. Since there is an estimated $1 trillion in illegal “naked” short sales (Financial Wire, 2004), which have been alleged to be related to the activities of organized crime (Weiss, 1997),6 enforcing the requirement that short sellers deliver securities they sell like any other seller would result in a short squeeze that would send stock market prices soaring, as those short sellers had to buy back the securities they sold to deliver the shares they had never borrowed.7 Most importantly, however, such a policy would inhibit the bankruptcy of the thousands of firms that have been shorted out of existence (Financial Wire, 2005) simply because of a short-term liquidity crisis.

The real estate and mortgage crisis itself could possibly be resolved by allowing defaulting mortgagors to refinance with shared appreciation mortgages (SAMs) that would lower their payments in return for the lending institution receiving a share in the

future appreciation on the home (Murphy, 2007). The SAMs could possibly be standardized to both reduce legal costs and also potentially create a secondary market for them in the form of SAM pools in which investors seeking diversification into residential real estate might be interested. By replacing foreclosure solutions with SAMs, less homes would be put on the market for sale, thereby reducing the downward pressure on real estate prices. The cycle of falling real estate prices leading to more mortgage defaults and foreclosures, which cause further drops in real estate prices that prompt more foreclosures, might therefore not only be stopped but even reversed.

Conclusion

By analyzing the root causes of the financial crisis, it is possible to estimate the costs of resolving that crisis utilizing current policies of bailing out investors who made poor investment decisions. Although the cost of the bailout may be staggering, cheaper solutions appear to exist. In any event, it would seem imperative that the financial managers of the future be better educated in the art of credit analysis.

Endnotes

1.The huge market for Alternative-A or “liar loans” that required no documentation

of income or assets but generated large fees for mortgage bankers, who sold them to other investors (Zibel, 2008), may never have existed without such guarantees.

2.Callaghan and Murphy (1998) have shown that bankruptcy is typically caused by

liquidity problems when external capital is typically not available. Murphy, Callaghan, and Parkash (2005) have demonstrated theoretically and empirically why external capital isn’t available during liquidity crises.

3.The failures of the two federal agencies were preceded in 2005 by a successful $2

million campaign by Freddie Mac to lobby Congress from restricting their own investments in higher-risk mortgages (Yost, 2008).

4.The required posting of additional collateral when the market value of a swap

contract becomes negative to a counterparty minimizes the risks associated with that counterparty going bankrupt and not fulfilling the terms of the contract. The risk of a domino effect remains, however, insofar as one large institution failing can lead to defaults on obligations without collateral requirements that can result in losses to other institutions which might thereby be driven into bankruptcy.

Such losses can exist on all over-the-counter trades with brokers and dealers that are not performed through the regulated markets like the futures and stock exchanges (Collins and McMahon, 2008).

5.The actual costs of the bailout will vary with the various methods employed.

These include payoffs on the debts that are guaranteed by the government (such as those of rescued bankrupt firms and mortgages in default), losses resulting from buying up assets privately or in the markets (such as mortgage-backed securities), and losses on financing provided to bankrupt firms to keep them afloat (that provide inadequate returns to the government in comparison to those available on other assets of similar risk).

6.The extensive resources an international criminal consortium dominated by

emigrants from the former Soviet Union has allocated to financial market manipulation since the 1991 overthrow of communism there (Friedman, 2000) may be connected to the increase in both the complaints and the significance of the illegal naked shorting. The fact that many of the naked short sales are currently rumored to emanate in some form from unauthorized USA stock listings on the Berlin Stock Exchange (Koh, 2005), which promotes itself (e.g., in its brochure entitled “Boerse Berlin Bremen” under the heading “Schwerpunkte des internationalen Angebots) as listing more U.S. stocks than any other foreign exchange in the world and having market makers with connections to Eastern Europe, also supports this very tentative hypothesis, albeit only circumstantially. 7.In an attempt to mitigate the financial crisis, the SEC began in late September

2008 to temporarily restrict short selling of financial service stocks by inhibiting brokers from initiating new short positions unless they delivered shares against existing short positions, thereby requiring short sellers such as hedge funds to switched to shorting other stocks and thus leading to no overall benefit to the stock market (Favel, 2008). Although short selling illiquid companies out of business can occur with traditional legal short selling and synthetic short positions via the option exchanges (Murphy, Callaghan, and Parkash, 2008), the costs of holding legal short positions can become extremely high with heavy shorting activity (Jones and Lamont, 2002). Since heavy shorting activity might be likely when the stock values of viable companies short of cash are manipulated down, ending the naked shorting might lead to especially large inhibitions on manipulative shorting activities. It is interesting in this context to observe that there had been one effort to impose delivery requirements on September 18, 2008, and the result was the stock market rose substantially at the end of that day as many shorts were squeezed to buy back to cover their naked positions (even though it doesn’t appear that there was full compliance). In any event, the

enforcement of the rules apparently was reduced in scope on the following day to only financial service stocks for reasons that are not completely clear. Complaints from hedge funds (and their brokers), which were finding spreads in the market soaring to as high as 700% as a result of the short squeeze, may have resulted in so many complaints (Favel, 2008) and outright refusals to buy back at such costs that the SEC backed off from enforcing the delivery rules.

References

E. Altman. “Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate Bankruptcy.” Journal of Finance 23 (1968), 589-609.

J. Aversa. “Fed Eyes Plan to Fund Short-Term Business Loans.” Associated Press (October 7, 2008).

Boni, L., 2006. Strategic Delivery Failures in U.S. Equity Markets. Journal of Financial Markets 9, 1-26.

M. Buchanan. “Crazy Money.” NewScientist (July 19, 2008), 32-35.

J. Burns. “Former Ratings-Firm Officials Blame Conflicts for Rosy Views.” Wall Street Journal (October 23, 2008), A4.

J. Callaghan and A. Murphy. "An Empirical Test of a Stochastic Cash Flow Theory of Evaluating Credit." Advances in Financial Planning and Forecasting 8 (1998), 31-51.

D. Collins and C. McMahon. “Great Bailout of 2008: What’s Next.” Futures (November 2008), 28-36.

F. Duffee. “Estimating the Price of Default Risk.” Review of Financial Studies 12 (1999), 197-226.

E. Elton, M. Gruber, D. Agrawal, and C. Mann. “Explaining the Rate Spread on Corporate Bonds.” Journal of Finance 56 (2001), 247-277.

G. Favel. “Sold Short.” Futures (November 2008), 32.

FinancialWire. “StockGate: The Tune May Have Changed, But the Song is the Same.” Investors Business Daily (June 25, 2004).

FinancialWire, 2005. “Regulation SHO Gets Confuser and Confuser as Listing ‘Disappear’.” Investors Business Daily (January 28, 2005).

M. Glantz and J. Mun. The Banker’s Handbook on Credit Risk. Elsevier: Burlington (2008).

B. Jameson. “The Blunders that Led to Catastrophe.” NewScientist (September 27, 2008), 8-9.

C. Jones and O. Lamont. “Short-sales Constraints and Stock Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 66 (2002), 207-239.

P. Koh. “Stung by the German Connection.”: Euromoney (April 1, 2005), 1.

R. Merton. “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: A Further Note.” Journal of Finance 29 (1974), 449-470.

G. Morgenson. “Behind Insurer’s Crisis: Blind Eye to a Web of Risk.” New York Times (September 28, 2008).

C. Morris. “Fed's $1.6 Trillon Bet: The $700-Billion Wall Street Bailout Was Only the Half of It.” Washington Independent (October 14, 2008).

A. Moses and S. Harrington. “Company Bond Risk Surges on Argentina Default Concerns.”Bloomberg (October 23, 2008).

A. Murphy. “A Discounted Cash-Flow Model of Fixed-Income Securities Subject to Multiple Calls." Southern Economic Journal 55 (1988), 21-36.

A. Murphy. Scientific Investment Analysis. Quorum Books: Westport (2000).

A. Murphy, J. Callaghan, and M. Parkash. “Shorting Down Value.” Presented at the 2005 Southern Finance Association (SFA) conference.

A. Murphy. “An Analysis of SAM Pricing in the UK.” Presented at the 2007 European Financial Management Association (EFMA) meeting.

NewScientist. “Crunchonomics.” July 19 (2008a), 5.

NewScientist. “Blinded by Science.” September 27 (2008b), 5.

PIA Connection. “Congress Exempted Credit Default Swaps from State Gaming Laws in 2000.” October 15 (2008).

R. Shiller. “Homes are a Risky Long-Term Investment.” TIAA-CREF (Summer 2005),

19-22.

E. Simon. “Meltdown 101: What are Credit Default Swaps?” Kansas City Star (October 26, 2008).

Weiss, G. “The Mob is Busier than the Feds Think.” Business Week (December 15, 1997), 130.

L. Woellert and D. Kopecki. “Moody’s, S&P Employees Doubted Ratings, E-Mails Say.” Bloomberg online (October 22, 2008), https://www.360docs.net/doc/fd11015586.html, /apps/news?pid=20601087&sid=a2EMlP5s7iM0&refer=home

Yost. “AP IMPACT: Mortgage Firm Arranged Stealth Impact.” Associated Press (October 20, 2008).

A. Zibel. “Liar Loans Threaten to Prolong the Crisis.” Huffington Post (August 18, 2008).

国内十大雅思培训机构排名

1麦考瑞雅思 已具有近10年英语和雅思培训经验,全国唯一开设在复旦大学城的专业雅思培训机构,唯一雅思承诺保分班,唯一突破中国学生写作口语瘸腿的创新性教学,写作口语成绩普遍高出社会平均分70%左右,唯一每天13小时《雅思高分技巧课+训练课》复合式教学体系,大学氛围,省级重点高中的管理模式,坚持高强度、大容量、出高分,得到了复旦大学高校教师和复旦内部大学生及上海大学生的普遍认可,享有极高的声誉,尤其是在写作口语双7分方面极为擅长。适合零基础、高中生、大学生在短期内的快速突破雅思6—8分。 麦考瑞雅思06年即开始G类移民类雅思培训,对G类雅思5分—8分都有丰富的教学和应试经验,每年都有G类学员在麦考瑞雅思的帮助下,取得了雅思4个6分,4个7分,总分和7分等,成功技术移民或投资移民到澳洲、美国、加拿大、新西兰等国家。 麦考瑞雅思低调而务实,从不做广告,除了江浙沪皖,仍有北京、河北、湖南、四川、内蒙等全国各地学员慕名而来。2010年度,麦考瑞雅思在沪江网被万名(ielts)《2010年度学员最满意的雅思培训机构》,并被央视CCTV、新华网等权威媒体报道班级成功故事,成为上海8万考生雅思7分实战人气排名第一和教学质量最好的专业雅思培训。 2新东方雅思 新东方教育科技集团(New Oriental Education & Technology Group )成立于1993年11月16日。经过十多年的发展,新东方教育科技集团已发展成为一家以外语培训和基础教育为核心,拥有短期语言培训系统、基础教育系统、教育研发系统、出国咨询系统、文化产业系统、科技产业系统等多个发展平台,集教育培训、教育研发、图书杂志音响出版、出国留学服务、国际游学服务,新东方在线教育、教育软件研发等于一体的大型综合性教育科技集团。2006年9月7号,新东方教育科技集团在美国纽约证券交易所成功上市,成为中国第一家在美国上市的教育机构。 3环球雅思

中国培训机构排行榜

●中国培训机构排行榜 ● ●根据2013-2014年中国教育培训行业的发展,现在慢慢转向为在线教育,不 再是以前的传统式教育。现在大多数培训机构都是以面授加网授同步进行教学,满足学员需求。 ● ●在这么众多的培训机构里,有加盟的,有连锁的。中国大大小小的培训机构 上万家,到底哪些培训机构最好,最适合我们理想的学习环境。深圳爱培训网为大家整理出以下中国十个最为出色的培训机构! ● ●一、新东方教育科技集团 ● ●培训项目:英语、厨师、出国留学、托福、雅思等。 ● ● ●

● ●中国培训机构排行榜---新东方教育集团 ● ●学校简介:新东方创办于1993年,20年专注教育培训,累积培训学员超过1600 万,从早教到成人,业务涵盖早教、学前、小学、中学、四六级、考研、出国考试、留学咨询、英语能力提升、国际游学、国际教育、图书、网络课堂等50多所学校,30000多名教职员工,旨在为学员提供一站式终身学习服务。 ● ●新东方教育科技集团已发展为一家以外语培训和基础教育为核心,拥有短期 语言培训系统、基础教育系统、职业教育系统、教育研发系统、出国咨询系统、文化产业系统、科技产业系统等多个发展平台,集教育培训、教育研发、图书杂志音响出版、出国留学服务、职业教育、新东方在线教育、教育软件研发等于一体的大型综合性教育科技集团。 ● ●学校优势:网授+面授同步进行、学校师资力量雄厚,中国老品牌教育培训 机构。 ● ●二、学而思教育 ● ●培训项目:小学奥数、英语、语文,初高中数学、物理、化学、英语、语文。●

● ● ●中国培训机构排行榜---学而思中小学教育 ● ●学校简介:2010年10月20日,学而思教育在纽约证券交易所正式挂牌交易, 成为国内首家在美国上市的中小幼课外教育培训机构。 ● ●学而思以“给孩子受益一生的教育”为使命,秉承“激发兴趣、培养习惯、 塑造品格”的教育理念,不仅关注学生学习成绩的提高,更关注学生学习兴趣的激发、学习习惯的培养和思维模式的塑造。为满足孩子多元的教育需求,学而思开展小班、1对1、网校等多种形式的教育服务,旗下拥有摩比思维馆、学而思培优、学而思网校、智康1对1、E度教育网五个子业务品牌,在各自细分领域都处于领先地位。 ● ●学而思还发展了国内布局完整的中小幼教育专业门户网站群——e度教育 网。e度网由育儿网、幼教网、奥数网、中考网、高考网、留学网等多个网

哪个雅思培训机构最好

哪个雅思培训机构最好? 哪个雅思培训班好?哪个雅思培训机构最好这应该是广大考雅思们最关注的问题。每次看到都是感触良多,我想到大家选择雅思培训学校的心情的时候,就真的想借给每位雅思考生一双慧眼,让他们把这些培训学校都看的清清楚楚、明明白白。 雅思考试费用不菲,培训价格更高,简直可以说高的离谱,学费几千甚至上万的雅思培训学校比比皆是。那如何选择雅思培训学校呢?我总结了以下几点注意事项,希望对大家有帮助。 一、雅思培训机构的口碑 俗话说得好:金杯,银杯,不如老百姓的口碑!选择雅思培训机构之前一定要多听取周围参加过培训同学的意见,做到心中有数。而对于通过网络搜索学校好坏的同学,一定要谨慎,慎重选择,因为网络上的职业枪手无以计数。 二、学校的师资 目前国内有很多知名雅思培训机构,其中不乏连锁或者加盟的,多数培训学校的老师都是本土化,如果哪家学校的宣传上给老师的包装冠以“北京”,“著名”,“学者”之类的名师,大家可要留意了,很多都是假的。其次老师的稳定性,如果学校的授课老师不断变换,对培训效果就会无法保障,报培训班之前一定要了解授课老师情况,有

的学校虽然打出了什么外教或者是名师的招牌,其实这些老师甚至连从业资格都没有这样我们怎么期待他们能给我带来英语能力的提高! 三、雅思学校课程设置 专业的雅思学校会根据学生不同英语基础开设课程,例如长期班、基础班、提高班、强化班等。这里建议大家最好选择一对一的雅思课程,在教学上会更有针对性,学习效果也显著。如果基础不同,采取一勺烩的做法,那你需要敬而远之。 四、能为学员提供相关服务 一个专业的雅思培训学校,会为学员提供很多的专业服务。例如:雅思写作批改,雅思口语交流机会,学前、学中、学后的模考等等。如果能提供这些服务并贯穿整个雅思学习的过程,那你可以优先选择了! 作为中国在线英语培训的领先者,引入欧美授课新理念,一直以来都认真聆听学员的心声,专注于提高学员的英语口语能力,使之成为最高性价比抉择的首选出国前英语雅思培训机构。易格英语利用专门的音频视频软件,通过在线学习的形式为学员提供一对一的专业辅导。他们最大的特色就是英美专业外教,一对一辅导以及免费试听。因为是在线培训的方式,所以培训不受时间、地点的限制,因为省去了场地和往返的费用,真正做到为每位学员节省每一分钱。全国官

上海雅思培训机构排行榜

上海雅思培训行业分析报告 ——专业解读上海雅思培训怎么选?

上海雅思培训行业分析报告 ——上海雅思培训机构怎么选? 随着雅思考试的持续火热,各种线上线下培训也余温不减。市面上的雅思培训机构被“吹”得天花乱坠,考生也被弄得晕头转向。诚然,不同的考生选择雅思培训机构关注的重点不一样,但是有四点是必须要看的。另外,相对于这四个必看点,考生容易陷入的一些误区,在此也为大家列出,以供参考。 第一,看口碑不看品牌 品牌的响亮很大程度在于机构广告费用的投入,及公司宣传策略的选择。大家在衡量一个机构质量的同时,不要仅凭平日里的印象进行选择,最好能先咨询参加过相关机构培训的朋友或同学,由他们进行推荐或者听取他们的建议。 部分知名度较高的培训机构内部培训效果难以评判,据一些参加过相关机构培训的考生反应,其培训效果与预期落差很大。 2 / 22

3 / 22 第二,看试听不看吹捧 考生在决定报考哪个培训机构前,一定要预约一次免费试听课。不要只听顾问老师的“吹捧”。通过试听,可以了解到这个机构老师上课的大致水平,从而对机构的教学实力做出评估。但是老师的教学水平千差万别,大家还需要对机构老师的整体水平做了解。如有条件还可以对相应授课教师做进一步的打听。 师资力量是一个机构培训实力的根本保证。大家需要从老师的教育背景、教学经验两方面去考察。有海外留学背景和国内知名院校背景相关专业的最好。另外,需要有三年及以上教学经验,且多次参加雅思考试并有高分学员培养经典案例的老师。 第三,看课程不看高分 课程设置是否全面,即有没有适合自己的 课程非常重要,切忌只看高分学员。高分学员的产生是有其自身英语基础的。一般考生要获取高分必须在适合自

十大英语培训机构推荐资料讲解

十大英语培训机构推荐 一、美联英语 美联英语,全球体验式英语培训领先品牌,是美联国际教育集团旗下最重要的产线品牌,一直提倡“会用,才算会英语”。从2006年开创至今,已覆盖14个省份、25个城市,拥有近100家教学中心。多年来,美联英语一直秉持体验式英语的教学理念,以轻松灵活的教学方式,每年为全球3万余名学员提供专业、高端的英语教育。美联英语更开创多种英语学习方法和课程,满足不同英语水平学员的切实需要,让学员能够在职场、学校、生活上真正运用英语。 特点:口语培训,独特的体验式英语培训的教学方法,教学中给学员力争还原真实的英语交流环境。欧美国家外教跟你面对面对话,教你最地道的口语。如果说把自己扔在国外是学英语的好方法,美联英语是把国外的语言环境搬到了美联英语的中心里。 二、新东方英语 简介:新东方学校成立于1993年,并于2006年成功在美国上市,语言培训一直是新东方的核心竞争力。 特点:学英语的都知道,新东方在应试方面的培训全国一流。托福雅思GRE,四级六级,专四专八,老师会教你各种考试方面的技巧。新东方解决了很多中国人应付考试的问题,很多考托福的学生都在新东方接受过培训

三、昂立英语 上海市昂立进修学院前身为交大昂立外语培训中心,1991年成立,是全国首家大学生发起的勤工助学组织,取名“ONLY”,长期的发展在培训行业积累了一定的口碑。 特点:价格、开课种类以及课时人数方面与新东方有些类似,但包含更多英语以外的培训班。 四、新航道 创始人是原新东方教师胡敏,与新东方培训有异曲同工之处,“雅思梦之队”、“托福国家队”、“考研英语梦之队”等为广大学子提供雅思、新托福、SAT、GRE、考研英语、四六级考试、英语口语、中学英语、综合英语等应试培训课程。 特点:明星老师口才比较好,上课气氛热烈,应试技巧比较有用。 五、李阳疯狂英语 简介:李阳疯狂英语是在中国本土土生土长的实用高效的英语学习方法,在广大校园有很大的影响力。 特点:多以训练营、夏令营等短期全封闭培训为主,作为一种交新朋友、集体生活的体验对于学生来说,参加一次这样的英语培训也很不错。

国内十大(ielts)雅思培训机构排名

国内十大(ielts)雅思培训机构排名相关资讯讯息 1麦考瑞雅思 已具有近10年英语和雅思培训经验,全国唯一开设在复旦大学城的专业雅思培训机构,唯一雅思承诺保分班,唯一突破中国学生写作口语瘸腿的创新性教学,写作口语成绩普遍高出社会平均分70%左右,唯一每天13小时《雅思高分技巧课+训练课》复合式教学体系,大学氛围,省级重点高中的管理模式,坚持高强度、大容量、出高分,得到了复旦大学高校教师和复旦内部大学生及上海大学生的普遍认可,享有极高的声誉,尤其是在写作口语双7分方面极为擅长。适合零基础、高中生、大学生在短期内的快速突破雅思6—8分。 麦考瑞雅思06年即开始G类移民类雅思培训,对G类雅思5分—8分都有丰富的教学和应试经验,每年都有G类学员在麦考瑞雅思的帮助下,取得了雅思4个6分,4个7分,总分6.5和7分等,成功技术移民或投资移民到澳洲、美国、加拿大、新西兰等国家。 麦考瑞雅思低调而务实,从不做广告,除了江浙沪皖,仍有北京、河北、湖南、四川、内蒙等全国各地学员慕名而来。2010年度,麦考瑞雅思在沪江网被万名(ielts)《2010年度学员最满意的雅思培训机构》,并被央视CCTV、新华网等权威媒体报道班级成功故事,成为上海8万考生雅思7分实战人气排名第一和教学质量最好的专业雅思培训。 2新东方雅思 新东方教育科技集团(New Oriental Education & Technology Group )成立于1993年11月16日。经过十多年的发展,新东方教育科技集团已发展成为一家以外语培训和基础教育为核心,拥有短期语言培训系统、基础教育系统、教育研发系统、出国咨询系统、文化产业系统、科技产业系统等多个发展平台,集教育培训、教育研发、图书杂志音响出版、出国留学服务、国际游学服务,新东方在线教育、教育软件研发等于一体的大型综合性教育科技集团。2006年9月7号,新东方教育科技集团在美国纽约证券交易所成功上市,成为中国第一家在美国上市的教育机构。 3环球雅思 广州市环球精英培训中心作为国内规模最大并首家在美国上市的连锁外语培训机构之一,为中国民办教育创新做出巨大贡献。12年来以驰名独特的“环球实用应试教学模式”,迅速发展成为具有全国(ielts)雅思、托福、SAT、GRE、PTE、少儿英语、BETS、BEC商务英语、职称英语、国际预科课程、四六级、外教口语、中教听说、新概念英语、词汇语法发音、夏冬令营、法德西意多语种、留学文书写作中心、职业网校、英语网校、政府及企业团培、英美公派奖学金申请、大学国际课程委培、英语教材开发等项的综合性学校及大型网校,成为第一个中国教育行业旗舰连锁机构,被称为“中国人的英语学习强国”。 4新航道雅思 新航道国际教育集团(是由英语教育专家胡敏教授率领一批国内外语言培训界精英及专家、学者共同创办,美国国际数据集团(IDG)和全球著名的教育培训机构美国KAPLAN国际

十大英语培训机构排名

十大英语培训机构排名 1、新东方 简介:新东方学校成立于1993年,并于2006年成功在美国上市,语言培训一直是新东方的核心竞争力。 影响力:闻名遐迩的应试培训,英语四六级、雅思、托福等考试技巧传授得不错,应试品牌效用很强大。 特点:明星老师口才比较好,上课气氛热烈,价钱相对实惠。 不足:应试技能传授多过语言的培训,上课人数较多。据说笑话每期一样,课件每期一样,不过对于应试来说很有效果。 师资:中教、外教 上课模式:课堂面授,大班上百人,小班十余人 面对对象:大学生出国考试 2、英孚教育 简介:1965年,一位名叫Bertil Hult的瑞典年轻人创办了EF 英孚教育。1994年进入中国市场的英孚教育,基于各大城市布点宣传较多,网络搜索排名第二。 影响力:老外开的公司,品牌宣传投入大,知名度、费用很高的英语培训“贵族”机构之一。 特点:局限于大城市,高档写字楼的教学环境,英语学习氛围较好。学习时间自由,要自制力较好和有品质要求的学员。 不足:价格较贵,学习期限多为一年以上,2万以上,课时数比较少单价较高。 师资:中教、外教 上课模式:面授为主,辅助在线预习等学习,一对4+大班课+在线学习 面对对象:成人商务人士 3、环球雅思 简介:雅思是最受语言培训网民关注的语言考试,市场上存在众多以雅思辅导起家的语言培训机构,市场竞争激烈。2001年成立的环球雅思则以3.9%的关注度排名第三。 影响力:一如期名字,在雅思考试这一块是绝对的权威,要移民出国的语言考试选择这错 不了。 特点:针对考试开设听力、口语、写作、阅读方面的针对性课程,适合专项突破。 不足:大班教学,更偏向应试,口语课时数较少。 师资:中教、外教

国内十大(ielts)雅思培训机构排名

国内十大(ielts)雅思培训机构排名 国内十大(ielts)雅思培训机构排名相关资讯讯息 1麦考瑞雅思 已具有近10年英语和雅思培训经验,全国唯一开设在复旦大学城的专业雅思培训机构,唯一雅思承诺保分班,唯一突破中国学生写作口语瘸腿的创新性教学,写作口语成绩普遍高出社会平均分70%左右,唯一每天13小时《雅思高分技巧课+训练课》复合式教学体系,大学氛围,省级重点高中的管理模式,坚持高强度、大容量、出高分,得到了复旦大学高校教师和复旦内部大学生及上海大学生的普遍认可,享有极高的声誉,尤其是在写作口语双7分方面极为擅长。适合零基础、高中生、大学生在短期内的快速突破雅思6—8分。麦考瑞雅思06年即开始G类移民类雅思培训,对G类雅思5分—8分都有丰富的教学和应试经验,每年都有G类学员在麦考瑞雅思的帮 助下,取得了雅思4个6分,4个7分,总分6.5和7分等,成功技术移民或投资移民到澳洲、美国、加拿大、新西兰等国家。麦考瑞雅思低调而务实,从不做广告,除了江浙沪皖,仍有北京、河北、湖南、四川、内蒙等全国各地学员慕名而来。2010年度,麦考瑞雅思在沪江网被万名(ielts )《2010年度学员最满意的雅思培训机构》,并被央视CCT V、新华网等权威媒体报道班级成功故事,成为上海8万考生雅思7分实战人气排名第一和教学质量最好的专业雅思培训。 2新东方雅思 新东方教育科技集团(New Oriental Education & Technology Group )成立于1993年11 月16日。经过十多年的发展,新东方教育科技集团已发展成为一家以外语培训和基础教育为核心,拥有短期语言培训系统、基础教育系统、教育研发系统、出国咨询系统、文化产业系统、科技产业系统等多个发展平台,集教育培训、教育研发、图书杂志音响出版、出国留学服务、国际游学服务,新东方在线教育、教育软件研发等于一体的大型综合性教育科技集团。2006年9月7号,新东方教育科技集团在美国纽约证券交易所成功上市,成为中国第一家在美国上市的教育机构。 3环球雅思 广州市环球精英培训中心作为国内规模最大并首家在美国上市的连锁外语培训机构之一,为中国民办教育创新做出巨大贡献。12年来以驰名独特的“环球实用应试教学模式”,迅速发展成为具有全国(ielts)雅思、托福、SAT、GRE、PT E、少儿英语、BET S、BEC商务英语、职称英语、国际预科课程、四六级、外教口语、中教听说、新概念英语、词汇语法发音、夏冬令营、法德西意多语种、留学文书写作中心、职业网校、英语网校、政府及企业团培、英美公派奖学金申请、大学国际课程委培、英语教材开发等项的综合性学校及大型网校,成为第一个中国教育行业旗舰连锁机构,被称为“中国人的英语学习强国”。 4新航道雅思 新航道国际教育集团(是由英语教育专家胡敏教授率领一批国内外语言培训界精英及专家、学者共同创办,美国国际数据集团(IDG)和全球著名的教育培训机构美国KAPLAN国际教育集团参与战略投资的国际化语言教育机构。下辖教育文化发展公司、培训学校、留学服

前十教育培训机构排名(更新篇)-教育培训联盟网

前十教育培训机构排名(更新篇) --教育培训联盟网 除了大学之外,还想学习一些额外知识人通常都会选择一些教育培训机构,要想真正学到知识,应该去一些知名度比较高的学校。那教育培训机构哪些比较好?哪些教育培训机构比较出名呢?什么教育培训机构比较有保障?教育培训联 盟网小编为大家整理了十大教育培训机构排行榜,就一起来看看下面的十大教育培训机构排行吧。 前十教育培训机构排名 1新东方 (集教育培训/教育产品研发/服务等于一体的大型教育科技集团,美国上市,北京新东方教育科技(集团)有限公司) 2学而思教育 (国内最具知名度的中小学教育培训机构之一,中小学教育培训领先品牌,北 京学而思教育科技有限公司) 3安博教育 (国内第一个真正以升学与就业两大关键需求为导向的全国性教育服务品牌,美国上市公司,安博教育集团) 4学大教育 (目前国内个性化教育培训领域的领先者,教育培训机构十大品牌,美国上市 公司,北京学大信息技术有限公司) 5环球雅思 (国内规模最大并在美国上市的连锁外语培训机构之一,国内知名连锁培训机构,北京环球天下教育科技有限公司) 6正保远程教育 (北京高新技术企业,具备网络教育资质、经教育部批准开展远程教育的专业公司,北京东大正保科技有限公司) 7弘成教育 (国内首个成功登陆海外资本市场的网络教育全面服务提供商,十大教育培训机构品牌,弘成科技发展有限公司) 8北大青鸟 (我国最大IT职业教育机构之一,致力培养中国IT技能紧缺型实用人才,北京阿博泰克北大青鸟信息技术有限公司) 9巨人教育 (国内中小幼教育领先品牌,极具品牌影响力的教育连锁机构,行业竞争力企业,大型综合教育集团,巨人教育集团) 10中公教育 (国内公职类职业培训规模最大的现代化职业教育机构,职业教育服务业领先企业,极具影响力的教育连锁机构)

雅思培训费用是多少呢

雅思培训费用是多少呢? 近年来,杭州的英语培训机构如雨后春笋,随之而来的是雅思培训班的价钱也就众说纷纭了,但是实话实说,价钱跟教学质量还是成正比的。所以大家在选择的时候不要盲目去看价格。下面小编就以杭州新航道https://www.360docs.net/doc/fd11015586.html,为例,为大家介绍一下雅思培训费用是多少,大家可以了解一下。 1.雅思培训费用是根据班型来定的。班级主要分为大班、小班和一对一,相信大家也肯定知道,人数越多的话费用也会越低一点。基础比较好的学生大多数会选择大班进行强化,基础一般的话选择小班的比较多,当然也有基础很好,但是想冲刺更高分的也会选择小班进行学习。一对一的话一般是想要快速提高的学生选择的比较多,或者基础不是很好的,因为一对一的学习模式是比较有针对性的。所以班级人数越少价格相对就越贵。 2.雅思培训班费用是根据基础来定的。因为每个人的基础都有不同的,所以有的人需要上入门,有的人需要上强化。有的考生基础不是很好,但是需要有一定的成绩来使自己有资格去申请学校,所以这种情况下只能通过基础的课程使自己一点点提高。所以入门级的课程和强化段的课程费用也是不同的。基础越好费用就会越低。 3.雅思培训班费用是根据目标分数来定的。大家每个人的目标都不同,申请的学校不同,所以对于成绩的要求也是不同的,这时候就会有6分班、6.5分班、7分等的区别。所以目标分不同,班级不同,费用也就不同了。基础越差,要求的分数越高,那么价格就会贵一点。 4.雅思培训班费用是根据课时来定的。这个是最直观的一点。有的课程时间是200个课程和课程时间100个课时的费用也肯定是不一样的。因为学生的基础不同,所以要根据自己的基础来选择的,基础弱一点的课时相对会久一点,那么价格也会相对高一点。

雅思英语培训班是否需要报名

雅思英语培训班是否需要报名? 雅思考试是出国留学生必不可少的一重要科目,而且想要证明自己英语情况,很多成年人也用英语来测验,造成雅思英语培训班日益火爆,那雅思英语培训班还需要报名吗? 为解决大家的困惑,哒哒英语小编为大家整理了有关雅思英语培训班的相关信息,快来学习一下吧! 报考雅思的考生每年都在增长,所以雅思培训班应运而生。根据考生多样化的需求,雅思培训班开设了不同的班型、课程。然而针对雅思培训市场现象,大家都褒贬不一,社会上对于是否报名雅思培训班有不同的看法。 一、雅思培训班市场现象 我们先来说一说雅思培训班市场现象。举一个例子,今年23岁的李文倩毕业于上海复旦,去年暑假她却像复习高考一样为雅思考试做着准备GRE;为

了进一步提高自己的英语能力,李文倩报名参加了在学校附近的一个雅思培训班,于是每天的生活不像别人一样吃喝玩乐,而是背单词,做没完没了的训练题,埋头苦读于题海。 像李文倩一样,还有很多人为了完成出国留学的目标,大部分都参加过托福或雅思英语培训课。但是这些培训课程主要还是向考生介绍考试形式,以及针对不同类型题目的解题技巧。以前李文倩在做雅思阅读的时候总是会一口气从头读到尾,从不做标记。但是,上了雅思培训课之后,她掌握一些更高明的考试技巧,通过标注关键词快速找到答案。这样子尝试之后答题效率和准确性果然有所提高。 但是仍然会有考生即使掌握了考试技巧,却不能取得满意的成绩。张伟名曾经参加过的雅思培训班的目标保6争7,但是最后她取得的分数却并不理想,只有5.5分。 二、学校里的老师怎么看待雅思培训班教学 今年45岁的吴霞是清华大学的一名语言老师,提到现在市面上的雅思培训班之类的培训课程,她明确表示:现在这些培训课程大部分都是以传授考试技巧为主,但是大幅度提分仍然取决于学生整体的语言水平。掌握考试技巧只能

杭州最好的雅思培训学校是哪家好不好

IELTS备考资料杭州朗思教育

杭州最好的雅思培训学校是哪家|好不好 在雅思考试中,听力部分对词汇要求较高,要求考生在做填空题时拼写对相应单词,因此也就要求我们熟知雅思听力中的高频词汇。根据雅思听力的题目设置,我们不难发现,Section 1和Section 2都是校园生活场景,也就是survival scenario,都是我们日常并大量掌握生活中会遇到的场景,如租房,办银行卡,旅游,咨询等等,这些场景都将是我们在未来出国留学的时候,必然且会经常遇到的生存场景。 因此,对于在听力材料Section 1和Section 2中涉及的词汇必然是全部和这类非常生活化的真实场景相关的,我们提前熟知这类场景下的高频词汇,能够有效帮助我们理解听力材料,并且减少在填空题中遇到生词的概率以获得更高的准确率。下面,本文就把这类生存场景进一步划分成如下几个场景: Living scenario:Renting,Banking,Shopping,Travelling,Enquiry,Sports,Party,Exhibition,Library,Job hopping Culture scenario:Leisure life,Social life 下面,就简单介绍一下这几类常见的场景词汇,各位同学们在背单词的过程中,可以按照这些场景分类归类记忆以提高背单词的效率。下面就拿Renting租房场景和Banking银行场景来说明一下每个场景一般都有什么类型的词汇,如何来有效分类记忆。 Renting中会遇到的词汇包括 人:tenant房客,landlord房东,landlady女房东 房子类型:flat公寓,villa别墅,hall of residence宿舍(英式),dormitory宿舍(美式), homestay 住家

十大教育培训机构排名

十大教育培训机构排名文件编码(GHTU-UITID-GGBKT-POIU-WUUI-8968)

我国十大教育培训机构排名 新东方(集教育培训/教育产品研发/服务等于一体的大型教育科技集团,美国上市,北京新东方教育科技(集团)有限公司) 学而思教育(国内最具知名度的中小学教育培训机构之一,中小学教育培训领先品牌,美国上市公司,学而思国际教育集团) 安博教育(国内第一个真正以升学与就业两大关键需求为导向的全国性教育服务品牌,美国上市公司,安博教育集团) 学大教育(目前国内个性化教育培训领域的领先者,教育培训机构十大品牌,美国上市公司,总部设在北京,学大教育集团) 环球雅思(国内规模最大并在美国上市的连锁外语培训机构之一,国内知名连锁培训机构,北京环球天下教育科技有限公司) 正保远程教育(纽约上市,高新技术企业,具备网络教育资质、经教育部批准开展远程教育的专业公司,京东大正保科技有限公司) 弘成教育(国内首个成功登陆海外资本市场的网络教育全面服务提供商,十大教育培训机构品牌,总部设在北京,弘成教育集团) 北大青鸟(我国最大IT职业教育机构之一,致力培养中国IT技能紧缺型实用人才,北京阿博泰克北大青鸟信息技术有限公司) 洪恩教育(知名教育产品开发商和教育解决方案提供商,以学前教育为主的高新技术企业,北京洪恩教育科技股份有限公司) 火星时代(最早进入中国电脑动画领域的企业之一,中国最具价值培训品牌之一,高新技术企业,北京火星时代科技有限公司)

如ATA,诺亚舟教育,笑笑教育,海文教育,朗阁,绿光教育,邦德,山木培训,阳光教育,新思维,尚德机构,巨人教育,海天教育,ABC教育,万学教育,太奇MBA培训,厦门旅游培训中心,北京建工培训中心,书城培训BCT,沃德教育培训中心,易达教育,中国气象局培训中心,大山外语学校,天才宝贝FasTracKids等这些比较着名的教育培训机构品牌利用现已形成的品牌优势,借以不断增长的市场规模,审时度势,抓住市场脉搏,采取“直营+特许加盟”混合型发展模式,快速复制成熟赢利模式,占领全国市场份额。而小型教育企业或初创教育机构选择加盟成熟的品牌教育企业,共享规模效应,更是企业快速成长的最佳策略。

相关文档
最新文档